History of economic inequality
The history of economic inequality is the study of the evolution of the uneven distribution of wealth or income throughout history between groups in a society, or between societies.
Theories
[edit]According to Simon Kuznets the rise in inequality is unavoidable with the birth of an Industrial Revolution, as it needs a dense concentration of capital to allow industrialisation. Afterwards, the level of inequality will decrease over time as industrialists need to employ qualified labors to complete ever more complexified tasks. Thus wage increases.
Economist Branko Milanović challenges this "naturalistic" approach of the evolution of inequality, deeming that there is nothing natural in it, but solely the product of industrial dispute. Thomas Piketty goes as far as stating that the historical rise or decrease in inequality in capitalism is but contingent,[1] and that industrial dispute and ideology are the means to transform the evolution of inequality within society.[2]
Prehistory and first civilizations
[edit]History of economic inequality goes as old as the history of civilizations and military conquests. American economist Thorstein Veblen states that first "barbarian" civilizations wage wars when meeting one another because of scarcity of ressources, which would have allowed the creation of a "predatory spirit". Glory and theft became thus masculin virtue as most physically able were those sent on the frontline to fight. Veblen explains that this predatory spirit initiated inequality of gender, for at some point men began to consider women of the ennemy tribe as genuine war trophies, thus implying objectivisation and economic domination on women by men.[3]
Antiquity
[edit]Milton Friedman argues that from antiquity to nowadays, in every country, the governors of societies have used the creation of money to unofficially, quickly and arbitrarily impose very heavy taxes, thereby increasing the power and wealth of the governors to the detriment of the common people.[4] By way of example, in the 4th century, the state of Constantinople devalued its copper currency, largely owned by the poor, in favor of the rich, thus increasing economic inequalities between rich and poor people.[5]
Middle Ages
[edit]Europe
[edit]According to Stephen Rigby, an economist specializing in medieval economic history, the conservative ideology of 12th-, 13th- and 14th-century Europe warranted the level of inequality, in particular by denouncing sharp wage rises as a challenge to the feudal social order. Rigby points out that intellectuals of the time relied heavily on the Bible and Aristotle's theses. As such, taking up Aristotelian theories,[a] the theologian Gilles de Rome asserted in the 13th century that economic inequalities were the natural product of the hierarchy between men, and that transforming the current social order would be an arbitrary, artificial decision, being contrary to natural peacefulness where men earn according to their ranking and their "social merit". Knighthood was thus worthy of all their wealth, since they were morally and physically superior to the peasantry, being ready to defend the community by the sword, which would mean a purer soul. 14th-century philosopher Christine de Pizan underlines that the social order was God's chosen system: one being born a peasant would mean that God had specifically decided to make one peasant, so one must obey the social order and hierarchy in order to follow God's plans.[6]
Nevertheless Rigby notes that in reality, the unequal social order was constantly challenged by medieval peasants. For instance, peasants sometimes worked slower or despoiled their masters as a form of resistance to the hierarchy.[6]
19th century
[edit]Revolutionary era
[edit]After the French Revolution, marketier spirit invaded every aspect of European lives, notably the soil.[7]
In France the Allarde decree of 1791 authorized every individual to develop his or her activity as he or she saw fit. As a result, peasants who owned certain plots of land could exclude other peasants for instance with partition, who depended on the solidarity of landowners to let their livestock eat the rest of the harvest. In this way, solidarity and social ties were broken, and inequalities between individuals increased rapidly.[7]
Up to the beginning of the Gilded Age and the Industrial Revolution, the United States was a relatively equal country, thanks to a rapidly growing demography which prevented the emergence of rent.
Industrial Revolution
[edit]While economic growth was dazzling thanks to the Industrial Revolution (it averaged 1.6%, compared with 0.3% in previous centuries), European societies were transformed into genuine rentier societies, with ever-increasing inequalities: Great Britain, Sweden and France became the three most unequal countries in history, with the top 10% of the population owning an average of 91%, 88% and 84% of national wealth respectively, while the bottom half of the population owned 1%, 1% and 2% of national wealth respectively.[8] The most unequal city in History is Paris, where the wealth of the richest 1% rose from 49.4% to 66.5% of the city's total wealth between 1810 and 1910, while over the same period the wealth of the poorest 50% of households fell from 1.3% to 0.2%.[9]
Worldwide speaking, the ratio of income held by the richest 10% to that held by the poorest 50% rose from 1800% to 4100% between 1820 and 1900.[10]
Conditions were so precarious that children as young as 4 were hired as workers for particularly dangerous tasks in the textile and mining industries, by 1840 the life expectancy of French workers had dropped from 24 to 19 years relatively to 1740.[11] Nevertheless, on March 22, 1841, Villermé's work prompted the French government to pass the "Loi relative au travail des enfants employés dans les manufactures, usines et ateliers" law, abolishing work for children under 8 years of age, work exceeding 8 hours a day for children aged 8 to 12, and work exceeding 12 hours a day for children aged 12 to 16. Until the end of the 19th century, similar laws were passed in England, the United States, Denmark, Switzerland, Belgium, Italy and the Netherlands.[12]
Daron Acemoğlu considers that the "nature of technology" didn't have a neutral role in the evolution of inequality during the Industrial Revolution: increasingly efficient automation began to replace workers, worsening their working conditions, stagnating wages and increasing working hours by up to 20%. Weavers were the hardest hit by automation: in England, hourly wages fell by 30 to 40%.[13]
From the Gilded Age onwards, the emergence of trusts brought the level of inequality in North America closer to that of European societies: in 1920, 2% of Americans owned 50% of the country's wealth, while two-thirds of the poorest owned almost nothing.[14]
20th century
[edit]Pre-war Era
[edit]The figures revealed at the beginning of the twentieth century flabbergasted a majority of economists, statisticians and politicians: In 1919, Irving Fisher, a liberal, put the question of extreme inequality at the heart of current stakes in the United States, as this hyper-unequal distribution would threaten the very foundations of American society. He proposed as a solution to tax direct inheritance by one-third, inheritance from grandparents by two-thirds, and inheritance from great-grandparents by the full amount; or the President of the French National Assembly, Joseph Caillaux, also a liberal, who confessed to being deeply shocked by the figures on the situation in France, and succeeded in convincing a majority of deputies to pass the first progressive income tax, before the Senate vetoed it in 1909:[15][16]
Nous avons été conduits à croire, à dire que la France était le pays des petites fortunes, du capital émietté et dispersé jusqu'à l'infini. Les statistiques que le nouveau régime successoral nous fournit nous obligent à en singulièrement rabattre. [...] Si l'on estime, dis-je, à 200 milliards la fortune en capital possédée par les Français, on s'aperçoit que 27% de ce total, soit 55 milliards, sont entre les mains de 18.000 personnes [pour une population de 41,2 millions de Français], et que 37% du même total, 75 milliards, sont entre les mains de 45.000 personnes. On constate enfin que les six dixièmes du capital national, représentant 120 milliards, sont entre les mains de 260.000 personnes. [...] Messieurs, je ne puis dissimuler que ces chiffres ont pu dans mon esprit modifier quelques-uns de ces idées préconçues auxquelles je faisais allusion tout à l'heure, qu'ils m'ont conduit à certaines réflexions. Le fait est qu'un nombre fort restreint de personnes détiennent la plus grande partie de la fortune du pays.
— Joseph Caillaux in 1907–1908 during Parlementary debates, L'impôt sur le revenu, 1910, p. 530-532
If politicians allowed this increase in inequality, it was first and foremost because France was seen as a country of small property owners, and it was unacceptable to involve the State in the economy. It was therefore out of the question to apply a progressive tax, which would have made it possible to tax large fortunes more and more, to the point of calling into question the notion of property, according to governments. In fact, France was the most backward country when it came to equality issues, since, according to politicians, France was the pioneer of equality because it was at the origin of the French Revolution, so social issues were not necessary, preventing any possible questioning in this area.[17]
In 1914 in Europe, overall the top 10% of wealthholders owned 90% of total wealth.[18]
Cold War
[edit]The post-war period was one of relative economic equality for both the Western and Eastern blocs.
Western Bloc
[edit]Golden age of welfare state
[edit]The Great Depression drastically changed many economists' and politicians' perceptions of capitalism, while the Second World War required massive reparations and reinvestment. As a result, many countries set about developing the welfare state in the second half of the 20th century.
Against a backdrop of extremely high inflation caused by the Second World War, and a very high level of capital destroyed by bombing, governments had no choice but to intervene on a massive scale to repair the damage done by the war, by making massive investments in the population as a whole. The result was the "Fordist compromise",[note 1] a high level of consumption spending, mass school enrolment and an easing of economic activity due to the collapse of a rent-based economy through inflation and bombing. These various phenomena triggered exceptional economic growth in the developed countries during the Thirty Glorious Years. Thus economic growth was driven by equality.[19]
Daron Acemoğlu argues that 21st-century Fordism opened up new tasks to workers each time a task was automated, effectively increasing workers' wages unlike in the nineteenth century, thereby increasing consumption, and therefore the income of companies, which then began to produce more, and so on, forging a virtuous circle between economic growth and economic equality.[13]
This decline in inequality has led to the emergence of a middle-class homeowner. The wealth of the poorest 50% has risen to 5% of national net wealth, while that of the middle 40% (those between the richest 10% and the poorest 50%), which can be associated with the middle class, has risen to 45%.[19]
In France this era of prosperity was not disconnected from a certain form of mixed economy blending capitalism and socialism: at its peak, 30% of national capital was nationalized, and this rate rose to almost 50% for industrial capital.[20]
Anglo-Saxon countries are particularly keen on this spirit of equality, and were the first to set up the welfare state: the United States introduced the Social Security Act (SSA) in 1935 and the Fair Labor Standards Act (FLSA) in 1938, and England the National Health Service (NHS) in 1948. These two countries also have the highest marginal tax rates in history, reaching a threshold of 84% and 94% respectively;[19][21] over the period 1932–1980, the top marginal income tax rate in the United States averaged 81%.[19]
Liberal revival
[edit]The context of stagflation in the 70s and 80s seemed to call into question the usefulness of the welfare state, in favor of the emergence of a neoliberal movement led by economist Milton Friedman. From the 1980s onwards, this led to lower taxes and the privatization of public enterprises in developed countries, notably under the impetus of Ronald Reagan in the US, Margaret Thatcher in the UK, Helmut Schmidt in Germany and Jacques Delors in France.
From 1980 to 2000, on average the top income tax rate in OECD countries fell from 58% to 50.3%, before dropping to 42.5% in 2021.[22]
Milton Friedman condones these privatizations and tax cuts by explaining that the state is as inefficient, if not less so, than private enterprise, and that negative taxation is preferable to progressive taxation, since the latter would discourage the richest from working.[note 2][4]
Yet according to Thomas Piketty, there is no statistically significant evidence to suggest that this rise in inequality and lower taxation of the wealthiest has boosted growth since the 1980s.[19]
Eastern Bloc
[edit]Communist era
[edit]The Soviet system in the USSR is economically very equal, so in Soviet Russia, Filip Novokmet estimates that the top 10% of income earners held 2.2 to 2.7 times the national average income (compared with 4.5 times in 2015 in Russia), and the top 1% of income earners held 3.5 to 5.5 times the national average income (compared with 20 times in 2015 in Russia).[23]
Thomas Piketty nevertheless qualifies these figures: a large proportion of inequalities in the USSR can be found in payment in kind, notably in the form of gifts of housing, passes... in short, privileges that are difficult to quantify.[24]
Jacques Sapir, an economist specializing in the Russian economy, believes that although economic gender inequalities were officially insignificant, the existence of a Black market in which men were the majority participants, while women tood care of household chores, greatly increased economic gender inequalities.[note 3][25]
Post-communist era
[edit]The collapse of the Soviet bloc in 1991 prompted liberal economists from both the Soviet and capitalist blocs to privatize the former communist countries as quickly as possible, in particular by means of a shock therapy known as voucher privatization, whereby all rights to collectivized enterprises are distributed fairly to all, who can freely sell their property rights for a given price.[26][27]
Thomas Piketty argues that voucher privatization prompted wealthy landowners to buy up a huge number of property rights, thereby rapidly increasing the level of inequality in post-Soviet countries, a policy which is at the root of the Russian oligarchy. The economist deplores the fact that a third way, different from the "communist disaster" and the ultra-liberal logic, has not been adopted.[28]
21st century
[edit]Since the liberal revival inequality has started to rise all around the world. Granted, poverty and extreme poverty declined, but inequalities between developed and developing countries, between capitalists and workers, and between low-skilled and highly skilled workers have risen sharply. Between 1980 and 2021, the income of the richest 10% in Europe rose from 27% to 36%, and in the United States from 35% to 47%.[29]
Globally the poorest 50% hold 2% of the world's wealth,[note 4] compared with 76% for the richest 10%, of which 38% goes to the richest 1%, and 12% to the richest 0.01%.[note 5] As a result, wealth inequality will have increased by 50% between the poorest 50% and the richest 0.01% between 2008 and 2022.[30]
Many economists fear that inequalities will continue to grow in the 21st century unless governments intervene on a massive scale.
Present day
[edit]The United States is experiencing in the 21st century an unprecedented level of inequality: whereas on the eve of the Great Depression – which was partly caused by inequalities between workers and capitalists – the richest 1% owned 24% of the country's income, in 2019 this rate is 27%. It's worth pointing out that from 1980 to 2015, where the incomes of the poorest 50% of Americans stagnated perfectly,[note 6] the incomes of the richest 1% tripled.[note 7][31][32]
Worldwide, in 2005 the Gini index rose to 0.70 points from 0.65 points.[33] More specifically, in the United States, from 1970 to 2018, the Gini coefficient associated with net incomes rose from 0.65 to 0.75, while in France this coefficient fell from 0.37 to 0.29.[34] As for economic growth, the World Inequality Lab estimates that since 1995, 38% has benefited multimillionaires, compared with 2% of growth benefiting the world's poorest 50%, and since 2020, two-thirds of growth has benefited the richest 1%.[22]
Lucas Chancel estimates that in 2021, the top 10% of the world's income earners will have 5.2 times the average income, while the poorest half of the population will earn 0.17 times the world average. The economist also analyses that, while income inequalities between countries have been reduced since 1982, inequalities within countries have increased.[10]
This rise in inequality is partly explained by the development of tax havens and shell companies, which have prompted governments to reduce their taxes to prevent the wealthiest from fleeing the country. In fact, a 10% increase in the tax rate reduces the number of top foreign athletes in the same country by the same amount. In fact, in the Nordic countries, the richest 0.1% place 30% of the amount they were supposed to pay in taxes in tax havens.[35]
And yet, tax havens could be tackled quite easily, notably through the introduction of a global tax, regulations on law firms and sanctions dedicated to countries refusing to be fiscally transparent. According to Gabriel Zucman, the failure to combat tax havens is not due to a lack of solutions, but to a deliberate political choice.[36]
As for gender inequalities, excluding China, economic inequalities between men and women have been steadily narrowing worldwide since 1990, although equal parity is far from being achieved: on average, men earned 2.22 times more than women in 1990, compared with 1.86 times more today.[10]
Since 2010, in response to rising inequality, ecological pressures and, in some countries, lower taxes on the rich than on the middle classes, groups of hundreds of millionaires around the globe have been calling for governments to tax them more. These include the Anglo-American group Patriotic Millionaires, created in 2010, the Austro-German group Tax me now, created in 2022, and the international group Proud to pay more, which signed an open letter at the World Economic Forum in Davos in 2023 and 2024. These groups are made up of young millionaires who are more aware of the issues of climate, taxation, inequality and global poverty, as economist Dominique Plihon explains: "The new generation [of millionaires] is also more aware of the convergence of crises. Climate crisis, fiscal crisis, economic crisis and democratic crisis are intrinsically linked, which makes the new generation all the more keen to change things", however, according to Dominique Plihon, another more likely underlying reason would be to seek to mitigate the resolution of extreme inequalities so as not to be taxed too much in the future.[22][37][38][39][40]
Forecasts
[edit]Thomas Piketty laments not so much our current situation as the trend we're heading towards; as the United States has demonstrated, there is a great risk that developed countries will massively apply liberal policies in the future until they return to a level of inequality close to that of the early 20th century, which will make it all the more difficult for developing countries to create a strong state to invest in human capital. This trend risks recreating a "rentier society" where elites remain the same, innovation is slow and the economy is sclerotic.[19]
Artificial intelligence is also likely to significantly increase economic inequality, as school enrolment has stopped growing to the benefit of wealthy wage earners and digital companies.[41] According to some estimates, artificial intelligence could not only increase inequalities, but also make workers more precarious: in 2014–2015, it was estimated that 7% of skilled jobs and 45% of jobs in general would be threatened by 2050,[35][42] but these figures date from before the acceleration - let's even say explosion - in the development of artificial intelligence since OpenAI, an IMF study from 2024 considers that 60% of jobs will be seriously threatened by artificial intelligence in developed countries by 2040 (compared with 40% on a global scale), although the IMF explains that this could lead to a significant increase in employees' income if artificial intelligence is used to complete their tasks.[43]
Economist Daron Acemoğlu fears that the aim is not to complete and facilitate workers' tasks, but to make them compete, to substitute them with artificial intelligence; he believes that the machine no longer makes it possible these days to unlock new tasks, which ends up purely substituting for the worker leading to unemployment, even though the worker is for the moment more productive than artificial intelligence,[13][35] which seems to be confirmed by the IMF study, showing that a third of workers are at risk of being purely substituted by artificial intelligence (compared with a quarter supplemented by AI), with uncertainties over the positive effects on future wages.[43]
References
[edit]- ^ Piketty, Thomas (2021). Une brève histoire de l'égalité [A brief history of equality] (in French). Éditions Points. pp. 20–21.
- ^ Piketty, Thomas (2019). Capital et idéologie. Les livres du nouveau monde. Éditions du Seuil. pp. 1585–1589. ISBN 978-2-02-133804-1.
- ^ Thorstein Veblen (1899). Théorie de la classe de loisir. Gallimard. ISBN 978-2-07-029928-7.
- ^ a b Friedman, Milton (2010). Capitalisme et liberté. Translated by André Fourçans. Leduc.s éd. ISBN 978-2-84899-369-0.
- ^ Anonymous. De rebus bellicis (in Latin).
- ^ a b Rigby, Stephen H. (2015). Justifying Inequality: Peasants in Medieval Ideology. In Peasants and Lords in the Medieval English Economy: Essays in Honour of Bruce MS Campbell (pp. 173–197). (lire en ligne [ PDF ])
- ^ a b Louis Dumont (2009) [1944]. "La grande transformation: aux origines politiques et économiques de notre temps". Tel. By Polanyi, Karl. Translated by Maurice Angeno; Malamoud, Catherine. Gallimard. p. 476. ISBN 978-2-07-012474-9.
- ^ Thomas Piketty (2019). "L'inégalité patrimoniale extrême: les sociétés de propriétaires européennes à la Belle Epoque (1880–1914)" (PDF). ens. Retrieved 13 January 2024.
- ^ Thomas Piketty (2021). "Une marche limitée et contrariée vers l'égalité: la concentration de la propriété en France, 1780–2020" (PDF). ens. Retrieved 18 January 2024.
- ^ a b c "Rapport sur les inégalités mondiales 2022. World Inequality Lab. Avril 2022. — Sciences économiques et sociales". ses.ens-lyon.fr. Retrieved 2024-01-27.
- ^ Louis René Villermé (2007) [1840]. Tableau de l'état physique et moral des ouvriers: employés dans les manufactures de coton, de laine et de soie. Futur antérieur. EMCC. ISBN 978-2-908291-90-2.
- ^ Manier, Bénédicte (2010). "1 Le travail des enfants dans l'Histoire". Le travail des enfants dans le monde. Repères. la Découverte. pp. 5–16. ISBN 978-2-7071-6709-5.
- ^ a b c Acemoglu, Daron; Johnson, Simon (2023). Power and progress: our thousand-year struggle over technology and prosperity. PublicAffairs. ISBN 978-1-5417-0253-0.
- ^ Harvard University, Willford Isbell (1915). The wealth and income of the people of the United States. New York, The Macmillan Company; London, Macmillan & Co., ltd. Retrieved 2024-01-13.
- ^ Piketty, Thomas (2019). Capital et idéologie. Les livres du nouveau monde (in French). Éditions du Seuil. pp. 240–243. ISBN 978-2-02-133804-1.
- ^ Joseph Caillaux (1910). L'impôt sur le revenu. Berger-Levrault & cie. pp. 530–532.
- ^ Piketty, Thomas (2019). Capital et idéologie. Les livres du nouveau monde. Éditions du Seuil. ISBN 978-2-02-133804-1.
- ^ piketty (2021-12-14). "The new global inequalities". Le blog de Thomas Piketty (in French). Retrieved 2024-01-28.
- ^ a b c d e f Piketty, Thomas (2013). Le capital au XXIe siècle. Les livres du nouveau monde. Éd. du Seuil. ISBN 978-2-02-108228-9.
- ^ Piketty, Thomas (2013). Le capital au XXIe siècle. Les livres du nouveau monde. Éd. du Seuil. ISBN 978-2-02-108228-9.
- ^ Piketty, Thomas (2019). Capital et idéologie. Les livres du nouveau monde. Éditions du Seuil. pp. 690–691. ISBN 978-2-02-133804-1.
- ^ a b c "Inégalités : des économistes et des millionnaires appellent le G20 à taxer les très riches". Le Monde.fr (in French). 2023-09-06. Retrieved 2024-01-28.
- ^ Filip Novokmet; Thomas Piketty; Gabriel Zucman (December 2017). "From Soviets to Oligarchs: Inequality and Property in Russia 1905–2016". World Weath & Income Database (2017/10).
- ^ Piketty, Thomas (2019). Capital et idéologie. Les livres du nouveau monde. Éditions du Seuil. pp. 897–899. ISBN 978-2-02-133804-1.
- ^ Sapir, Jacques (1984). Travail et travailleurs en URSS. Collection Repères. La Découverte. ISBN 978-2-7071-1445-7.
- ^ Piketty, Thomas (2019). Capital et idéologie. Les livres du nouveau monde. Éditions du Seuil. p. 917. ISBN 978-2-02-133804-1.
- ^ Sapir, Jacques (2002). Les économistes contre la démocratie: les économistes et la politique économique entre pouvoir, mondialisation et démocratie. Biblioth`eque Albin Michel Economie. Albin Michel. ISBN 978-2-226-13427-1.
- ^ Piketty, Thomas (2019). Capital et idéologie. Les livres du nouveau monde. Éditions du Seuil. pp. 924–925. ISBN 978-2-02-133804-1.
- ^ Thomas Piketty (2019). "Les inégalités de 1900 à 2020: Europe, Etats-Unis, Japon" (PDF). ens. Retrieved 13 January 2024.
- ^ "What's new about wealth inequality in the world?". WID – World Inequality Database. Retrieved 2024-01-28.
- ^ Thomas Piketty (2019). "Bas et hauts revenus aux Etats-Unis, 1960–2015" (PDF). piketty.pse.ens.fr. Retrieved 28 January 2024.
- ^ Piketty, Thomas (2019). Capital et idéologie. Les livres du nouveau monde. Éditions du Seuil. pp. 808–810. ISBN 978-2-02-133804-1.
- ^ Milanovic, Branko (2012-03-01). "Global inequality recalculated and updated: the effect of new PPP estimates on global inequality and 2005 estimates". The Journal of Economic Inequality. 10 (1): 1–18. doi:10.1007/s10888-010-9155-y. ISSN 1573-8701. Retrieved 2024-01-26.
- ^ Antoine Bozio; Bertrand Garbinti; Jonathan Goupille-Lebret; Malka Guillot; Thomas Piketty (July 2023). "Predistribution vs. Redistribution: Evidence from France and the United States" (PDF). Université de Liège.
- ^ a b c Banerjee, Abhijit V.; Duflo, Esther; Jaquet, Christophe (2020). Économie utile pour des temps difficiles. Les livres du nouveau monde. Éditions du Seuil. ISBN 978-2-02-136656-3.
- ^ Saez, Emmanuel; Zucman, Gabriel; Deniard, Cécile (2020). Le triomphe de l'injustice: richesse, évasion fiscale et démocratie. Les livres du nouveau monde. Éditions du Seuil. ISBN 978-2-02-141212-3.
- ^ France, Oxfam (2022-01-18). "" Taxez-nous " – Lettre ouverte de millionnaires". Oxfam France (in French). Retrieved 2024-01-26.
- ^ Jean-Loup Delmas (2024-01-15). "Va-t-on (vraiment) vers une nouvelle génération de riches au grand cœur ?". www.20minutes.fr (in French). Retrieved 2024-01-26.
- ^ "Davos : la lettre de 260 millionnaires pour payer plus d'impôts". France Culture (in French). 2024-01-17. Retrieved 2024-01-28.
- ^ "Des millionnaires appellent à payer plus d'impôts : " Je suis riche, taxez-moi ! "". Le Monde.fr (in French). 2023-10-23. Retrieved 2024-01-28.
- ^ Claudia Goldin; Lawrence F. Katz (2005). "The Race between Education and Technology: The Evolution of U.S. Educational Wage Differentials, 1890 to 2005". National Bureau of Economic Research. Working Paper Series. doi:10.3386/w12984.
- ^ "Four fundamentals of workplace automation | McKinsey". www.mckinsey.com. Retrieved 2024-01-18.
- ^ a b "Gen-AI: Artificial Intelligence and the Future of Work". IMF. Retrieved 2024-01-18.
Notes
[edit]- ^ Term coined by Michel Aglietta to describe the sharp rise in productivity made possible by Fordism, combined with the indexation of wages to productivity.
- ^ Milton Friedman claims that the negative income tax combines the advantages of both progressive and proportional taxation, since the negative income tax would be socially fairer and less disincentive because marginal taxation would be constant: an additional income of $500 or $1,000 would be taxed at the same percentage. Friedman's negative income tax has been widely publicized and successful in the USA since 1962, and the principle is still relevant today.
- ^ According to Jacques Sapir, illegal work (i.e. working in the underground economy) earned double or triple that of legal work. A quick calculation shows that a man's income was three to four times that of a woman.
- ^ In 1995, they held 1.5% of the wealth.
- ^ In 1995, the latter accounted for 7.5% of the world's wealth.
- ^ In real terms of 2015, in 1980 the average income of the poorest 50% was $15,988, compared with $16,186 in 2015, a real increase of $198.
- ^ In real terms of 2015, in 1980 the average income of the richest 1% was $428,781, compared with $1,305,301 in 2015, a real increase of 204%, or an annual increase in real income of 3.2%.
- ^ « Giles's defence of social hierarchy was thus based on Aristotle's claim that, "from the hour of their births, some men are marked out for subjection, others for rule". (Aristotle, Politics, ed. by Everson, I. 5 (p. 16)) »
Bibliography
[edit]- Piketty, Thomas (2014) [2013]. Capital in the Twenty-First Century. Harvard University Press. ISBN 978-0674430006.
- Piketty, Thomas (2020) [2019]. Capital and Ideology. Harvard University Press. ISBN 978-2-02-133804-1.
- Acemoglu, Daron (2023). Power and Progress: Our Thousand-Year Struggle Over Technology and Prosperity. PublicAffairs. ISBN 978-1541702530.