History of taxation in the United Kingdom
The history of taxation in the United Kingdom includes the history of all collections by governments under law, in money or in kind, including collections by monarchs and lesser feudal lords, levied on persons or property subject to the government, with the primary purpose of raising revenue.
Background
[edit]Prior to the formation of the Kingdom of Great Britain in 1707 and the United Kingdom in 1801, taxation had been levied in the countries that joined to become the UK. For example, in England, King John introduced an export tax on wool in 1203 and King Edward I introduced taxes on wine in 1275. Also in England, a Poor Law tax was established in 1572 to help the deserving poor, and then changed from a local tax to a national tax in 1601.[1] In June 1628, England's Parliament passed the Petition of Right which among other measures, prohibited the use of taxes without its agreement. This prevented the Crown from creating arbitrary taxes and imposing them upon subjects without consultation.
One of the key taxes introduced by Charles II was to help pay for the rebuilding of the City of London after the Great Fire in 1666. Coal tax acts were passed in 1667 and in 1670. The tax was eventually repealed in 1889.[2]
In 1692, the Parliament of England introduced its national land tax. This tax was levied on rental values and applied both to rural and to urban land. No provision was made for re-assessing the 1692 valuations and consequently they remained in force well into the 18th century.[3]
From 1707
[edit]Window tax
[edit]When the Kingdom of Great Britain came into being on 1 May 1707, the window tax, which had been introduced across England and Wales under the Act of Making Good the Deficiency of the Clipped Money in 1696,[4] continued. It had been designed to impose tax relative to the prosperity of the taxpayer, but without the controversy that then surrounded the idea of income tax. At that time, many people opposed income tax on principle because they believed that the disclosure of personal income represented an unacceptable governmental intrusion into private matters, and a potential threat to personal liberty.[5] In fact the first permanent British income tax was not introduced until 1842, and the issue remained intensely controversial well into the 20th century.[6]
When the window tax was introduced, it consisted of two parts: a flat-rate house tax of 2 shillings per house (equivalent to £17.53 in 2023) and a variable tax for the number of windows above ten windows. Properties with between ten and twenty windows paid a total of four shillings (comparable to £35.05 in 2023),[7] and those above twenty windows paid eight shillings (£70.11 as of 2023).[7][8]
Income tax
[edit]Duties on Income Act 1799 |
---|
Duties on Income (No. 2) Act 1799 |
---|
Duties on Income Act 1800 |
---|
Income tax was first implemented in Great Britain by William Pitt the Younger in his budget of December 1798 to pay for weapons and equipment in preparation for the Napoleonic Wars. Pitt's new graduated (progressive) income tax began at a levy of 2 old pence in the pound (1⁄120th) on incomes over £60 (£7,978 as of 2023),[7] and increased up to a maximum of 2 shillings (10%) on incomes of over £200. Pitt hoped that the new income tax would raise £10 million, but actual receipts for 1799 totalled just over £6 million.[6]
19th century
[edit]Pitt's income tax was levied from 1799 to 1802, when it was abolished by Henry Addington during the Peace of Amiens. Addington had taken over as prime minister in 1801, after Pitt's resignation over Catholic Emancipation. The income tax was reintroduced by Addington in 1803 when hostilities recommenced, but it was again abolished in 1816, one year after the Battle of Waterloo.
Addington's Act for a 'contribution of the profits arising from property, professions, trades and offices' (the words 'income tax' were deliberately avoided) introduced two significant changes. First, it allowed taxation at the source; for example, the Bank of England would deduct an amount, to be paid as tax, from interest paid to holders of gilt-edged securities. Secondly, it introduced schedules:
- Schedule A (tax on income from UK land)
- Schedule B (tax on commercial occupation of land)
- Schedule C (tax on income from public securities)
- Schedule D (tax on trading income, income from professions and vocations, interest, overseas income and casual income)
- Schedule E (tax on employment income)
Income not falling within those schedules was not taxed. (Later a sixth schedule, schedule F – tax on UK dividend income – was added.)
Although the maximum tax rate under Addington's Act was 5% – only one-half of the 10% allowed under Pitt's – the other changes resulted in a 50% increase in revenue, largely because they doubled the number of persons liable for the tax and somewhat expanded the scope.[6]
Pitt in opposition had argued against Addington's innovations; he adopted them largely unchanged, however, when he returned to office in 1805. The one major change he made was to raise the maximum rate back to the 10%, the rate in his original bill, in 1806. Income tax changed little for the duration of the Napoleonic Wars, despite changes in government.[6]
Nicholas Vansittart was Chancellor of the Exchequer in 1815, at the time of the Battle of Waterloo. He was inclined to maintain the income tax, but public sentiment was heavily against it, and predictably, the opposition championed its abolition. It was thus repealed in 1816 'with a thundering peal of applause'. In fact, the tax was so unpopular that Parliament ordered the destruction of all documents connected with it. This was more show than substance, for the King's Remembrancer had made duplicates and retained them.[6]
Under Peel
[edit]The general election of 1841 was won by the Conservatives with Sir Robert Peel as Prime Minister. Although he had opposed the unpopular income tax during the campaign, an empty Exchequer and a growing deficit gave rise to the surprise return of the tax in his 1842 Budget. Peel sought only to tax those with incomes above £150 per annum, and he reduced customs duties on 750 articles out of a total number taxed of 1,200. The less wealthy benefited, and trade revived as a consequence.[9][10] Peel's income tax was 7d in the pound (about 3%). It was imposed for three years, with the possibility of a two-year extension. A funding crisis in the railways and increasing national expenditure ensured that it was maintained. For Peel, the debate was academic. In 1846 he repealed the Corn Laws – which supported landowners by imposing tariffs on imported corn (wheat and barley) that was cheaper than that produced at home – and lost the support of much of his party. The Whigs resumed power the same year, to be joined by some notable 'Peelites'.[9]
Gladstone and Disraeli
[edit]The second half of the 19th century was dominated by two politicians – Benjamin Disraeli and William Ewart Gladstone.
A Conservative, Disraeli opposed Peel's repeal of the Corn Laws (which had inflated the price of imported grain to support home farmers). He was three times Chancellor of the Exchequer and twice Prime Minister.
Formerly a Conservative, Gladstone supported the repeal of the Corn Laws and moved to the opposition (Whigs, and from 1868 Liberals). He was four times Chancellor and four times Prime Minister – his final term starting at age 82.
Disraeli and Gladstone agreed about little, although both promised to repeal income tax at the 1874 General Election. Disraeli won – the tax stayed.
Gladstone spoke for nearly five hours introducing his 1853 Budget. He outlined plans for phasing out income tax over seven years (which the Crimean War was to upset), of extending the tax to Ireland, and introduced tax deductions for expenses 'wholly, exclusively and necessarily' incurred in the performance of an office – including keeping and maintaining a horse for work purposes. The 1853 Budget speech included a review of the history of the tax and its place in society, it is regarded as one of the most memorable ever made.
With the Whigs defeated in 1858, Disraeli returned as Chancellor and in his Budget speech described income tax as 'unjust, unequal and inquisitorial' and 'to continue for a limited time on the distinct understanding that it should ultimately be repealed'. But the Conservatives return to power was short-lived. From 1859 to 1866, the Whigs were back with Viscount Palmerston as Prime Minister and Gladstone as Chancellor.
Gladstone had set 1860 as the year for the repeal of income tax, and his Budget that year was eagerly awaited. Ill health caused it to be delayed and for his speech to be shortened to four hours. But he had to tell the House of Commons that he had no choice but to renew the tax. The hard fact was that it raised £10 million a year, and government expenditure had increased by £14 million since 1853 to £70 million (these figures should be multiplied by 50 for a modern equivalent).
Gladstone was still determined that income tax should be ended. When a select committee was set up against his wishes to consider reforms which might preserve it, he packed the committee with supporters to ensure that no improvements could be made. In 1866, the Whigs' modest attempts at parliamentary reform failed to win support in Parliament and the Conservatives returned to power, although with no overall majority. Disraeli succeeded where Gladstone had failed, seeing the Reform Bill of 1867 become law. This gave the vote to all householders and to those paying more than £10 in rent in towns – and so enfranchising many of the working class for the first time. Similar provisions for those living in the country came with Gladstone in 1884.
While Disraeli had gambled that an increased electorate would ensure a Conservative majority, and in 1868 he was prime minister, the election of that year saw the Liberals – as the Whigs had become – victorious under Gladstone. Income tax was maintained throughout his first government, and there were some significant changes made including the right to appeal to the High Court if a taxpayer or the Inland Revenue thought the decision of the appeal commissioners was wrong in law. But there was still a determination to end it. The Times, in its 1874 election coverage, said 'It is now evident that whoever is Chancellor when the Budget is produced, the income tax will be abolished'.
Disraeli won the election, Northcote was his Chancellor and the tax remained. At the time it was contributing about £6 million of the government's £77 million revenue, while Customs and Excise contributed £47 million. It could have been ended, but at the rate at which it was applied (less than 1%) and with most of the population exempt, it was not a priority. With worsening trade conditions, including the decline of agriculture as a result of poor harvests and North American imports, the opportunity never arose again.[11]
20th century
[edit]First World War
[edit]The war (1914–1918) was financed by borrowing large sums at home and abroad, by new taxes, and by inflation. It was implicitly financed by postponing maintenance and repair, and cancelling unneeded projects. The government avoided indirect taxes because such methods tend to raise the cost of living, and can create discontent among the working class. There was a strong emphasis on being "fair" and being "scientific". The public generally supported the heavy new taxes, with minimal complaints. The Treasury rejected proposals for a stiff capital levy, which the Labour Party wanted to use to weaken the capitalists. Instead, there was an excess profits tax, of 50 percent of profits above the normal prewar level; the rate was raised to 80 percent in 1917. Excise taxes were added on luxury imports such as automobiles, clocks and watches. There was no sales tax or value-added tax. The main increase in revenue came from the income tax, which in 1915 went up to 3s. 6d in the pound (17.5%), and individual exemptions were lowered. The income tax rate grew to 5s (25%) in 1916, and 6s (30%) in 1918.
Altogether taxes provided at most 30 percent of national expenditures, with the rest from borrowing. The national debt consequently soared from £625 million to £7.8 billion. Government bonds typically paid five percent. Inflation escalated so that the pound in 1919 purchased only a third of the basket it had purchased in 1914. Wages were laggard, and the poor and retired were especially hard hit.[12][13]
Purchase tax
[edit]Between October 1940 and 1973 the UK had a consumption tax called Purchase Tax, which was levied at different rates depending on goods' luxuriousness. Purchase Tax was applied to the wholesale price, initially at a rate of 33⅓ %. This was doubled in April 1942 to 66⅔ %, and further increased in April 1943 to a rate of 100%, before reverting in April 1946 to 33⅓ % again. Unlike VAT, Purchase Tax was applied at the point of manufacture and distribution, not at the point of sale. The rate of Purchase Tax at the start of 1973, when it gave way to VAT, was 25%. On 1 January 1973 the UK joined the European Economic Community and as a consequence Purchase Tax was replaced by Value Added Tax on 1 April 1973. The Conservative Chancellor Anthony Barber set a single VAT rate (10%) on most goods and services.
Income tax
[edit]This section needs additional citations for verification. (October 2022) |
UK income tax has changed over the years. Originally it taxed a person's income, regardless of whether they had a legal obligation to pass it on to another person and would not have had any benefit from it. Modern income tax is only due when a person receives income to which he or she is beneficially entitled. Since 1965, income tax only applies to natural persons; since then, companies are subject instead to corporation tax. These changes were consolidated by the Income and Corporation Taxes Act 1970. Also the schedules under which tax is levied have changed. Schedule B was abolished in 1988, Schedule C in 1996 and Schedule E in 2003. For income tax purposes, the remaining schedules were superseded by the Income Tax (Trading and Other Income) Act 2005, which also repealed Schedule F completely. The Schedular system and Schedules A and D still remain in force for corporation tax. The highest rate of income tax peaked in the Second World War at 99.25%. It was then slightly reduced and was around 90% through the 1950s and 60s.[citation needed]
In 1971 the top rate of income tax on earned income was cut to 75%. A surcharge of 15% kept the top rate on investment income at 90%. In 1974 the cut was partly reversed and the top rate on earned income was raised to 83%. With the investment income surcharge this raised the top rate on investment income to 98%, the highest permanent rate since the war.[citation needed] This applied to incomes over £20,000 (£263,269 as of 2023).[7]
The Government of Margaret Thatcher, who favoured taxation on consumption, reduced personal income tax rates during the 1980s in favour of indirect taxation.[14] In the first budget after her election victory in 1979, the top rate was reduced from 83% to 60% and the basic rate from 33% to 30%.[15] The basic rate was also cut for three successive budgets – to 29% in the 1986 budget, 27% in 1987 and to 25% in 1988; The top rate of income tax was cut to 40%.[16] The investment income surcharge was abolished in 1985.
Under the government of John Major the basic rate was reduced in stages to 23% by 1997.
21st century
[edit]Under Labour chancellor Gordon Brown, the basic rate of income tax was further reduced in stages to 20% by 2007. As the basic rate stood at 35% in 1976, it has been reduced by 43% since then. However, this reduction has been largely offset by increases in other regressive taxes such as National Insurance contributions and Value Added Tax (VAT).
In 2010, a new top rate of 50% was introduced on income over £150,000 p.a. In the 2012 budget, this rate was cut to 45% with effect from 6 April 2013.
In 2022, as part of the September 2022 United Kingdom mini-budget, then-Chancellor Kwasi Kwarteng announced his intention (subject to Parliamentary approval) to abolish the top 45% rate and to cut the basic rate from 20% to 19% from April 2023. (The "higher rate" was to remain unchanged.) Previously announced rises in National Insurance and corporation tax were also reversed. When it became clear that such approval would not be forthcoming, he announced cancellation of the top-rate reduction plan.[17]
Business rates
[edit]Business rates were introduced in England and Wales in 1990, and are a modernised version of a system of rating that dates back to the Poor Relief Act 1601. As such, business rates retain many previous features from, and follow some case law of, older forms of rating. The Finance Act 2004 introduced an income tax regime known as "pre-owned asset tax" which aims to reduce the use of common methods of inheritance tax avoidance.[18]
Devolution of Tax powers
[edit]The Scotland Act 2016 gave the Scottish Parliament full control over income tax rates and bands, except the personal allowance.[19] In 2017/18, the only notable difference between Scotland and the rest of the UK was that the higher rate limit was frozen in Scotland. However, the draft budget for 2018/19 proposed new rates and bands that would mark a real change from the rest of the UK.[20][needs update]
Start of tax year
[edit]Summary
[edit]British tax Acts in the middle of the eighteenth century said the tax year ran "from" 25 March. The use of "from" is crucial because the word has a special legal meaning which caused the tax year to begin one day later, namely, on 26 March.[a] The taxes charged annually in the mid eighteenth century were Land Tax and Window Tax.
The Calendar (New Style) Act 1750 elided eleven days from September 1752 but, despite this elision, the Window Tax tax year continued to run "from" 25 March 1753 (NS) until April 1758 when Parliament moved it to a year "from" 5 April.[21][b] The Land Tax year never changed.
In September 2021, the Office of Tax Simplification published a report considering the benefits, costs and implications of moving the end of the tax year from 5 April to either 31 December or 31 March. It concluded that although there was popular support for moving the date, there were different opinions on which date was best and that any change would take some time to implement.[22]
Legal rule
[edit]When a document or statute said a period of time was to run 'from' a date, an old legal rule provided that the period began on the following day. This rule of interpretation dates back at least to Sir Edward Coke's landmark work of 1628 called the Institutes of the Lawes of England.[23] Coke's book was written as a commentary on the 1481 treatise on property law by Sir Thomas Littleton. Hence the specialist use of "from" may originate much earlier than 1628. The key passage in the Institutes is short:
But let us return to Littleton … Touching on the time of the beginning of a lease for yeares, it is to be observed, that if a lease be made by indenture, bearing date 26 Maii &c to have and to hold for twenty one yeares, from the date, or from the day of the date, it shall begin on the twenty seventh day of May.[24] [Emphasis added.]
Coke's Institutes were an important source of education for lawyers and editions were published up to the nineteenth century. This is why tax acts in the eighteenth century used "from" 25 March in an exclusive sense to mean a period beginning on the following day. Numerous court cases have arisen because the technical meaning of from a date in acts and documents has been misunderstood.[25] The Office of the Parliamentary Counsel, which drafts legislation today, has published online drafting guidance which says the from a date formulation is ambiguous and should not be used.[26]
Perhaps the most important contemporary authority for the start of the Land Tax year is in An Exposition of the Land Tax by Mark A Bourdin of the Inland Revenue which was published in 1854. In a footnote on page 34 he says: "the year of assessment is from 26th March to the 25 March following".[27]
Bourdin does not use from in the strict sense required by Coke but it is clear that he believes the Land Tax year begins on 26 March and ends on the following 25 March.
In 1798 William Pitt made Land Tax permanent with the Land Tax Perpetuation Act 1798.[28] Section 3, for example, refers to "an assessment made in the year ending on the twenty fifth day of March 1799", which confirms the Land Tax year begins on 26 March. The Land Tax year remained essentially unchanged until the tax was abolished in 1963.
A number of authorities explain why the old tax year began on 26 March so that the addition of eleven days led directly to the modern tax year which begins on 6 April.[29][30][31]
Accounting convention
[edit]Accounting practice from time immemorial also took the same view. A quarter day, such as Lady Day which falls on 25 March, marked the end of an accounting period and not the beginning. This view is taken by leading authorities including The Exchequer Year,[32][33] The Pipe Roll Society[34] and Dr Robert Poole in two works.[35][36]
In the 1995 work Calendar Reform Dr Poole cites Treasury Board Papers at the National Archives under reference T30 12 and explains that, after the omission of eleven days in September 1752, Treasury quarterly accounts carried on being drawn up to the same four days but the dates had moved on by eleven days. He says:
... so the national accounts continued to be made up to end on the Old Style quarter-days of 5 January, 5 April, 5 July and 10 October.[37]
These were the old quarter days of 25 December, 25 March, 24 June and 29 September plus eleven days. Dr Poole's analysis is confirmed by a minute of the Board of Customs on 19 September 1752, shortly after the omission of the eleven days 3 to 13 September 1752 and not long before the first quarter day affected by the omission—Michaelmas 29 September 1752. The minute says:
On the correcting of the Kalendar all Quarterly Accounts and Payments of the Customs of what nature or kind 'soever are to be closed on 10th October—5th January—5th April and 5th July, And the Annual Accounts are to be made out from 5th January to 5th January in every Year.[38]
Eleven days added to prevent loss of tax?
[edit]Some commentators, such as Philip (1921),[39] have suggested the government added eleven days to the end of the tax year which began on 26 March 1752. They say this was done to avoid the loss of tax which they believe would otherwise have been caused by the omission of eleven days in September 1752. The Inland Revenue took this view in 1999 in a (subsequently deleted) note issued on the 200th anniversary of the introduction of income tax in 1799.[40]
In fact the British tax authorities did not add eleven days to the end of the tax year which began on 26 March 1752. They did not need to add eleven days because the taxes charged by the year captured artificial, deemed income, and not actual income. For Land Tax, the more important of the two, the amounts taxed were fixed sums linked to the market rental value of property in 1692 when the tax was introduced.[41] For Window Tax it was so much per window. The same tax was due regardless of the year length. Window Tax was a permanent tax and its year did not change until 1758 when the tax was recast and the tax year moved by eleven days to run "from" 5 April.[42] That meant a year which began on 6 April because of Sir Edward Coke's 1628 interpretation rule.[23]
The Land Tax year never changed after 1752 and continued to run "from" 25 March (Lady Day). The entire Land Tax code, running to 80 pages, was re-enacted every year until 1798 when it was made permanent. Hence there was ample opportunity to revise the date on which the Land Tax year began but no change was made.
Online editions of British statutes generally omit the annual Land Tax Acts because of their transitory nature. The National Archives at Kew holds printed statute series which include copies of all the Land Tax Acts. However, a few Land Tax Acts are available online including the last annual Land Tax Act for the year from 25 March 1798.[43] The 1798 Act uses the standard "from" formula and says in section 2:
that the sum of one million nine hundred eighty-nine thousand six hundred seventy-three pound seven shillings and ten-pence farthing ... shall be raised, levied and paid unto his Majesty within the space of one year from the twenty-fifth day of March 1798.[43] [Emphasis added.]
Income tax
[edit]William Pitt introduced the first income tax in 1799, and followed the Window Tax precedent by adopting a year which ran "from" 5 April.[44] That meant, once again, a year which began on 6 April, and this has remained the start of the year ever since. For example, Addington's Income Tax Act 1803 continued to apply "from" 5 April—in this case from 5 April 1803.[45] Again, this meant a year beginning on 6 April 1803.
Income tax was repealed temporarily in 1802 during a brief period of peace in the long war with France. The act which repealed the tax included a provision which permitted the collection of tax due for earlier years. This saving provision confirmed that Pitt's income tax year ended on 5 April:
Provided always, and be it enacted, That the said respective Rates and Duties …shall continue in force for the Purpose of duly charging to the said Rates and Duties all Persons … who shall not have been respectively charged to the said Duties for the Year ending on the fifth Day of April 1802, or for any prior year...[46] [Emphasis added.]
It was not until 1860 that income tax legislation consistently adopted a charging formulation of the kind recommended today by the Office of the Parliamentary Counsel to identify the income tax year. For 1860–61 the tax was applied "for a year commencing on 6 April 1860".[47] [Emphasis added.]
Section 48(3) of the Taxes Management Act 1880 later provided a definition of the income tax year for the first time and uses "from" in the modern sense:[47]
Every assessment shall be made for the year commencing and ending on the days herein specified.
- (3) As regards income tax—
- In Great Britain and Ireland from the sixth day of April to the following fifth day of April inclusive.[48]
Section 28 Finance Act 1919 provided a new shorthand way to refer to the tax year:
The expression "the year 1919–20" means the year of assessment beginning on the sixth day of April 1919, and any expression in which two years are similarly mentioned means the year of assessment beginning on the sixth day of April in the first mentioned of those years.[49]
Finally, following a review aimed at simplifying tax legislation, a new definition appeared in section 4 Income Tax Act 2007:
(1) Income tax is charged for a year only if an Act so provides.
(2) A year for which income tax is charged is called a "tax year".
(3) A tax year begins on 6 April and ends on the following 5 April.
(4) "The tax year 2007–08" means the tax year beginning on 6 April 2007 (and any corresponding expression in which two years are similarly mentioned is to be read in the same way).[50]
Incorrect explanation for 6 April tax year
[edit]An alternative explanation of the origin of the tax year is still found on some British tax websites.[c] This stems from a book published in 1921 by Alexander Philip.[39] The relevant passage is short:
A curious instance of the persistence of the old style is to be found in the date of the financial year of the British Exchequer. Prior to 1752 that year officially commenced on 25th March. In order to ensure that it should always comprise a complete year the commencement of the financial year was altered to the 5th April. In 1800, owing to the omission of a leap year day observed by the Julian calendar, the commencement of the financial year was moved forward one day to 6th April, and 5th April became the last day of the preceding year. In 1900, however, this pedantic correction was overlooked, and the financial year is still held to terminate of 5th April, as it so happens that the Easter celebration occurs just about that time—indeed one result is that about one-half of the British financial years include two Easters and about one-half contain no Easter date.
— Alexander Philip, The Calendar: its history, structure and improvement[39]
Philip does not give any reason for his view and Poole's analysis shows that it is incorrect. Philip does not cite any legislation or other authority. It is also worth noting that the "financial year" he mentions is not the same as the income tax year. The financial year is statutorily defined by the Interpretation Act 1978 as the year which ends on 31 March.[51] This repeats an earlier similar definition in section 22 Interpretation Act 1889.[52] This is the year for government accounting and for corporation tax. Poole gives a simpler explanation:
The twelve- rather than eleven-day discrepancy between the start of the old year (25 March) and that of the modern financial year (6 April) has caused puzzlement, [...] In fact, 25 March was first day of the [calendar] year but the last day of the financial quarter, corresponding to 5 April; the difference was thus exactly eleven days.[53]
— Robert Poole, Time's alteration : calendar reform in early modern England
See also
[edit]- Taxation in the United Kingdom
- History of inheritance taxes in the United Kingdom
- Taxation history of the United States
Notes
[edit]- ^ As explained at §Legal rule, below
- ^ 5 April NS is the equivalent of 25 March OS.
- ^ For example, EFN Ltd: "Why does the UK tax year end on 5th April?". 14 March 2014.
References
[edit]- ^ "The Poor Law". elizabethan-era.org.uk. Retrieved 8 October 2016.
- ^ Hylton B. Dale, "The Worshipful Company of the Woodmongers and the Coal Trade of London." Journal of the Royal Society of Arts (1922): 816–823. in JSTOR
- ^ Turner, Michael Edward; Mills, Dennis R., eds. (1986). Land and property: the English land tax 1692–1832. St. Martin's Press. ISBN 9780862992231.
- ^ Herber, Mark D (1997). Ancestral Trails: The complete guide to British genealogy and family history. Sutton Publishing Ltd. ISBN 0-7509-1418-1. p.416
- ^ Mill, John Stuart. "3". Principles of Political Economy. Vol. V. Section 5.
- ^ Jump up to: a b c d e "A tax to beat Napoleon". HM Revenue & Customs. A brief history of income tax. Archived from the original on 24 July 2010. Retrieved 9 December 2010.
- ^ Jump up to: a b c d UK Retail Price Index inflation figures are based on data from Clark, Gregory (2017). "The Annual RPI and Average Earnings for Britain, 1209 to Present (New Series)". MeasuringWorth. Retrieved 7 May 2024.
- ^ "Window Tax". Wolverhampton Archives. Archived from the original on 23 October 2006.
- ^ Jump up to: a b "Income tax is back". HM Revenue & Customs. A brief history of income tax. Archived from the original on 27 January 2013.
- ^ Gash, Norman (1971). Sir Robert Peel: The Life of Sir Robert Peel after 1830. pp. 291+, 318+, 459+.
- ^ "Gladstone vs Disraeli". HM Revenue & Customs. A brief history of income tax.
- ^ Taylor, A.J.P., English History 1914–1945 (1965) pp. 40–41.
- ^ Daunton, M.J., "How to Pay for the War: State, Society and Taxation in Britain, 1917–24", in English Historical Review (1996) 111# 443 pp. 882–919
- ^ Bartlett, Bruce. "Thatcher Economics". National Review. Archived from the original on 10 September 2005.
- ^ "Economy: 1979 Budget (Howe 1)". Hansard. 12 June 1979.
- ^ "Budget Statement (Mr. Nigel Lawson)". Hansard. 15 March 1988.
- ^ Parker, George; Payne, Sebastian; Pickard, Jim (3 October 2022). "Liz Truss backs down on 45p tax rate cut in major U-turn". Financial Times.
- ^ "REV BN 40: Tax Treatment Of Pre-Owned Assets". HMRC. Archived from the original on 9 July 2013. Retrieved 12 January 2011.
- ^ "Scottish Income tax 2017/18". Scottish Government. Retrieved 29 January 2018.
- ^ "Scottish income tax changes unveiled". BBC News. 14 December 2017. Retrieved 29 January 2018.
- ^ Pickering, Danby, ed. (1766). "31 Geo. II c.22". The Statutes at Large from the Magna Charta, to the End of the Eleventh Parliament of Great Britain, Anno 1761 [continued to 1806]. Vol. 22. J. Bentham. p. 269.
XXXI And be it further enacted by the authority aforesaid That from and after the fifth day of April one thousand seven hundred and fifty eight there shall be charged raised levied and paid unto his Majesty his heirs and successors the rates and duties upon houses windows or lights herein.
- ^ "Exploring a change to the UK tax year end date". Office of Tax Simplification. Retrieved 17 January 2024.
- ^ Jump up to: a b Coke, Sir Edward (1628). Institutes of the Lawes of England. Sometimes called "Coke on Littleton" because it contains Sir Thomas Littleton's 1481 treatise on property law with a commentary by Coke. Volume 1 at 46b. "Coke" is pronounced "Cook"
- ^ Coke Upon Littleton, Of tenant for yeares, page 46b.
- ^ See, for example, "Zoan v Rouamba". 2000. (EWCA Civ 8, [2001] 1 WLR 1509.)
- ^ "Guidance for members of the Office of the Parliamentary Counsel (OPC) who are drafting bills to be considered in Parliament". Office of the Parliamentary Counsel. 4 April 2024. paragraph 8.1.4.
- ^ Bourdin, Mark A. An Exposition of the Land Tax. Lincoln's Inn, London: T F A Day. p. 34.
- ^ Land Tax Perpetuation Act 1798 (38 Geo. 3. c. 60).
- ^ Poole (1995), p. 117, footnote 77.
- ^ Poole (1998), chapter 9, footnote 34.
- ^ Steel (2001), p. 5.
- ^ Richardson, H.G. (1925). "The Exchequer Year". Transactions of the Royal Historical Society. 8. Cambridge University Press: 171–190. doi:10.2307/3678321. ISSN 0080-4401. JSTOR 3678321. S2CID 154782015.
From the earliest times and for many centuries the year of account in the Exchequer ended at Michaelmas
- ^ C R Cheney (1945), Table III in Chapter 2 which lists the Exchequer Years from Henry I to William IV. Every year ends on the quarter day, 29 September..
- ^ "How were pipe rolls compiled?". The Pipe Roll Society. Archived from the original on 27 January 2019.
Each roll nominally covered the events of a year ending at Michaelmas (29 September), rather than the calendar year or the regnal year, which was used in the rolls produced by other government departments.
- ^ Poole (1995).
- ^ Poole (1998).
- ^ Poole (1995), p. 117.
- ^ National Archives, Kew. File CUST 29/1.
- ^ Jump up to: a b c Philip, Alexander (1921). The Calendar: its History, Structure and Improvement. Cambridge University Press. p. 24. OCLC 457646963. Retrieved 13 February 2020 – via Internet Archive.
- ^ "Of course it should be the 6th April!?". theexpgroup.com. 5 August 2009. Retrieved 18 November 2020.
HM Revenue & Customs are a very helpful lot and explained the reason why the tax year starts on 6 April as follows: 'In order not to lose 11 days' tax revenue in that tax year, though, the authorities decided to tack the missing days on at the end, which meant moving the beginning of the tax year from the 25 March, Lady Day, (which since the Middle Ages had been regarded as the beginning of the legal year) to 6 April'.
[This explanation repeats the error made by Philips (1921), as described below in #Old explanation for 6 April tax year. It no longer appears on the HMRC website.] - ^ See, for example, Report of the Commissioners of Inland Revenue 1870 (Report). p. 111.
There can be no doubt that both the apportionments to the counties by statute, and in that to the divisions by the Commissioners, the amounts were determined by reference to the assessments made under the first Act in 1692. In the Acts passed annually, or nearly so, for the next hundred years the Commissioners are specially directed to observe the proportions established in the reign of William and Mary, and this direction is repeated in Mr Pitt's Act of 1797.
- ^ Danby Pickering, ed. (1762). "XXII: An act for granting to his Majesty several rates and duties upon offices and pensions; and upon houses; and upon windows or lights; and for raising the sum of five millions by annuities, and a lottery, to be charged on the said rates and duties". The Statutes at Large: from the 30th to the 33rd year of King George II. Cambridge, Printed by Joseph Bentham. p. 270 [315]. (31 Geo II c.22) Section XXXI: "Window Tax".
- ^ Jump up to: a b "Chapter V: An Act for granting to his Majesty by a land tax, to be raised in Great Britain, for the Service of the Year one thousand seven hundred and ninety eight". The Statutes Revised Edition: Volume III: 11 George III to 41 George III. 1870. p. 461. (38 Geo. 3. c. 5)
- ^ Parliament of Great Britain (1799). "39 Geo. 3. c. 13. Income Tax Act 1799.". Statutes at Large. Vol. XLII volume. p. 55. See section 72 on page 86.
- ^ "Acts passed Anno Quadragesimo Tertio Georgii III Regis 43 Geo. III Cap. CXXII". The Law Journal, volume 2. 11 August 1803. p. 140.
An act for granting to his majesty until the 6th day of May next after the ratification of a definitive treaty of peace a contribution on the profits arising from property professions trades and offices
- ^ Thomas Edlyne Tomlins (4 May 1802). "42 George III, Cap. XLII". The Statutes of the United Kingdom of Great Britain and Ireland, Volume 1. p. 338.
- ^ Jump up to: a b Parliament of the United Kingdom (1860). "Income Tax Act 1860 (23 Vict c.14.)". A collection of the public general statutes passed in the twenty third and twenty fourth years of the reign of Her Majesty Queen Victoria. Being the second session of the eighteenth parliament of the United Kingdom of Great Britain and Ireland. p. 86..
- ^ Parliament of the United Kingdom (1880). "Taxes Management Act 1880 (43 & 44 Vict c.19)". The Law Reports: The Public General Statutes passed in the forty third year of the reign of her Majesty Queen Victoria 1880 with tables showing the effect of the session's legislation and a copious index. Vol. XVI. Article 48 (3)
- ^ Parliament of the United Kingdom (1919). "Finance Act 1919 (9 & 10 Geo 5 c.32)". irishstatutebook.ie. Retrieved 8 November 2020.
- ^ "Income Tax Act 2007", legislation.gov.uk, The National Archives, 2007 c. 3 Section 4
- ^ "Interpretation Act 1978: Schedule 1", legislation.gov.uk, The National Archives, 1978 c. 30 (sch. 1), retrieved 16 February 2024,
"Financial year" means, in relation to matters relating to the Consolidated Fund, the National Loans Fund, or moneys provided by Parliament, or to the Exchequer or to central taxes or finance, the twelve months ending with 31st March. [1889]
- ^ "Interpretation Act 1889" (PDF). legislation.gov.uk. Government of the United Kingdom. p. 13.
- ^ Poole (1995), footnote 77, page 117.
Sources
[edit]- C R Cheney, ed. (1945). A Handbook of Dates for students of British History. Revised by Michael Jones, 2000. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. ISBN 9780521778459.
- Poole, Robert (1995). "'Give us our eleven days!': calendar reform in eighteenth-century England". Past & Present (149). Oxford Academic: 95–139. doi:10.1093/past/149.1.95. JSTOR 651100.
- Poole, Robert (1998). Time's alteration: calendar reform in early modern England. UCL Press, Routledge Taylor & Francis. ISBN 9781857286229.
- Steel, Duncan (2001). Marking Time: The Epic Quest to Invent the Perfect Calendar. New York: Wiley. ISBN 9780471404217. (also available as e-book)
Further reading
[edit]- Beckett, John V. "Land Tax or Excise: the levying of taxation in seventeenth-and eighteenth-century England", in English Historical Review (1985): 285–308. in JSTOR
- Bernard, G. W. War, Taxation, and Rebellion in Early Tudor England: Henry VIII, Wolsey and the Amicable Grant of 1525 (1986)
- Braddick, Michael J. The nerves of state: taxation and the financing of the English state, 1558-1714 (Manchester University Press, 1996).
- Burg, David F. World History of Tax Rebellions: An Encyclopedia of Tax Rebels, Revolts, and Riots from Antiquity to the Present (Routledge, 2004)
- Carruthers, Bruce G. "From city of capital: Politics and markets in the English financial revolution." in The New Economic Sociology: A Reader (2004): 457-481.
- Cousins, Katherine. "The Failure of the First Income Tax: A Tale of Commercial Tax Evaders?." Journal of Legal History 39.2 (2018): 157-186. on 1799 tax; online
- Daunton, Martin. "Creating Consent: Taxation, War, and Good Government in Britain, 1688–1914." in The Leap of Faith (Oxford University Press, 2018).
- Daunton, Martin. Trusting Leviathan: the politics of taxation in Britain, 1799–1914 (Cambridge University Press, 2007)
- Dowell, Stephen. History of Taxation and Taxes in England (Routledge, 2013)
- Emory, Meade. "The Early English Income Tax: A Heritage for the Contemporary", in American Journal of Legal History (1965): 286–319. in JSTOR
- Fletcher, Marie M. "Death and taxes: Estate duty–a neglected factor in changes to British business structure after World War two." Business History (2021): 1-23. online
- Gardner, Leigh. Taxing colonial Africa: the political economy of British imperialism (Oxford University Press, 2012).
- Kennedy, William. English taxation, 1640–1799: An essay on policy and opinion (Routledge, 2018).
- Mollan, Simon, and Kevin D. Tennent. "International taxation and corporate strategy: evidence from British overseas business, circa 1900–1965." Business History 57.7 (2015): 1054-1081.
- O'Brien, Patrick K. "The political economy of British taxation, 1660‐1815", in Economic History Review (1988) 41#1 pp: 1–32. in JSTOR
- Pierpoint, Stephen. The Success of English Land Tax Administration 1643–1733 (2018) excerpt
- Rao, K. V. Ramakrishna. The British Approach Towards Taxation Customs And Excise (2009) online
- Shebab, F. Progressive Taxation: A Study of the Development of the Progressive Principle in the British Income Tax (1953) online
- Shirras, G. Findlay. and L. Rostas. The Burden of British Taxation (1942)
- Sloman, Peter. Transfer state: The idea of a guaranteed income and the politics of redistribution in modern Britain (Oxford University Press, 2019).
External links
[edit]- Lay summary in: Lewis, Paul (5 April 2020). "Why does the tax year really begin on 6 April". Blogspot. (Paul Lewis presents Money Box on BBC Radio 4.[1])
- HMRC; HM Treasury; Welsh Government; Scottish Government (25 July 2023). "Personal tax | Income Tax: detailed information". Gov.UK.
- ^ BBC Radio 4 Money Box Presenter Profiles Paul Lewis