Компенсация дифференциала
Дифференциал заработной платы - это термин, используемый в экономике труда для анализа связи между уровнем заработной платы и неприятными, рисками или другими нежелательными атрибутами конкретной работы. Компендирующий дифференциал, который также называется компенсационным дифференциалом заработной платы или выравнивающей разницей , определяется как дополнительная сумма дохода, которую должен быть предложен дан заданный работник, чтобы мотивировать их принять данную нежелательную работу, относительно других рабочих мог выполнить. [ 1 ] [ 2 ] Можно также говорить о компенсационном дифференциале для особенно желаемой работы, или о том, что обеспечивает особые преимущества, но в этом случае дифференциал будет отрицательным : то есть данный работник хотел бы принять более низкую заработную плату за особенно желательную работу , относительно других рабочих мест. [ 3 ]
Идея компенсации дифференциалов использовалась для анализа таких проблем, как риск будущей безработицы, [ 4 ] риск травмы, [ 5 ] риск небезопасного полового акта, [ 6 ] Монетарная стоимость работников помещается в свою жизнь, [ 7 ] и в объяснении географических различий в заработной плате. [ 8 ] [ 9 ] [ 10 ] [ 11 ]
Географические разницы в заработной плате
[ редактировать ]There is a wide literature dealing with geographical wage differentials. Following the neoclassical assumption of clearing labour markets, where there is a more attractive area to live in and if labour mobility is perfect, then more and more workers will move to this area which in turn will increase the supply of labour in this area and in turn depress wages. If the attractiveness of that area compared to other areas do not change, the wage rate will be set at such a rate that workers would be indifferent between living in areas that are more attractive but with a lower wage and living in areas which are less attractive and with a higher wage. Henceforth, a sustained equilibrium with different wage rates across different areas can happen.[2][12]
The theory
[edit]The theory of compensating wage differentials, by Adam Smith, provides a theoretical framework of the ideology behind pay differences. The theory explains that jobs with undesirable characteristics will compensate with higher wages compared to the popular, more desirable jobs, who provide lower wages to its workers.[13] Competition in labour markets ensures that the net advantages of different jobs will tend to equality. Thus, higher pay in some areas of the country is expected where the cost-of-living is higher while higher pay is also necessary to compensate for a less pleasant working environment. The rate of pay in the private sector represents (according to the hypothesis) the exact rate necessary to attract and retain staff. Thus all else equal a higher rate of pay in one area means that this area is less attractive (either has low amenity levels or higher cost-of-living). The pay offered in this area is set to counter the relative unattractiveness of the region. Some empirical studies have tried to test this assumption. Most of this research is interested in inter geographical wage disparities. The research ask the question: how can geographical wage differentials be explained?
Employment Benefits
[edit]Employees who receive employment benefits, like health insurance, are trading in higher wages for better benefits because the benefits are valuable to the employee and offered at a lower rate through their employer, compared to outside vendors. On the contrary, if an employer offers a health insurance plan with low coverage that is not attractive to employees, the wages at the firm will likely not be reduced due to the low participation in the health insurance plan. In this scenario, employees would prefer to receive higher wages and lower quality benefits. Transitioning the firm's expenses from wages to health insurance coverage allows the employees to receive quality health insurance by forgoing the option to get paid higher wages. Similar to the ideology of compensating wage differential where employees receive higher wages at undesirable/risky jobs and lower wages at safe/desirable jobs, receiving several employee benefits results in lower monetary compensation.[14]
Hedonic Wage Function
[edit]The hedonic wage function represents the assumption that employees maximize their utility in job selection to a budget constraint outlined by the labor market. The hedonic wage function graphically displays the compensating wage differential between a firm and its employees. The function's slope represents the best fit line going through the indifference curves, representing wages and the probability of injury while at work.[15] The function is upward sloping due to the parallel relationship between wages and the undesirable qualities of a job; the more undesirable the job is, the higher the wages employees are compensated for working at the company. The mean and variance of the function vary based on the data, whether the data is firm-level or employee-level data. The equilibrium of the hedonic wage function between employee wages and non-wage-related attributes for a particular job argues there is a minimal correlation to workers' preferences.[16]
Empirical results
[edit]Most of the empirical results from the literature attempt to decompose the geographical wage differentials according to human capital characteristics. Areas with more skilled workers will tend to have higher mean wages. Though, average wages may differ among different areas because they offer different levels of amenities. It is usually believed in economics that wages in areas where the level of amenity is high comparatively to other areas will be lower. Empirical research has attempted to measure area characteristics in order to measure this effect on average wages. Though, some characteristics may be attractive for some workers but because workers may have different utilities, other workers may not be attracted by these characteristics. The following assumption is usually made: workers among a similar occupation will share similar utility function, then it is possible to measure the characteristics of areas on the mean wage of a particular occupation. [citation needed]
Human capital
[edit]Some articles have brought evidence that wages differ across areas in different countries using a decomposition analysis of the mean wage.[17] In 1992, Reilly[18] used this decomposition technique[17] to decompose wage differentials between 6 local labour markets in the UK. The decomposition allows to decompose mean wage differences into two parts, one which is the consequence of individual characteristics in those 6 labour markets[note 1] and the other one which is due to unexplained differences. The author finds that the differences in wages between labour markets is at around 20%, and that between Aberdeen and Rochdale, 50% of this difference is explained by workers' characteristics, the other part is not explained. The unexplained differences can be thought of being consequences of differences in local areas attractiveness. Though this author does not give any evidence that this is the case. Similar results are obtained by García and Molina[10] for Spain[note 2] with data from 1994[note 3] Pereira and Galego[19] analysed wage differentials in Portugal using dynamics. They also found similar results to García and Molina[10] and to Reilly.[18][note 4]
Area characteristics
[edit]Part of the attractiveness of areas is the cost-of-living. An area with a lower cost-of-living should be more attractive than areas with an expensive cost-of-living. Unfortunately, it is difficult to measure within countries cost-of-living. In an article published in 1983, Shah and Walker[11] estimated a wage equation for male white workers in the UK using the general household survey of 1973[note 5] The cost-of-living proxy is taken from Reward Regional Surveys Ltd[20] which publish reports on cost-of-living and regional comparisons from 1974 up to at least 1996[21] The description of the construction of those cost-of-living is not clear.[21][note 6] Wage differentials change and sometimes are reversed when they introduce the cost-of-living, Scotland and the South East of England are worse off when introducing cost-of-living compared to the Midlands regions. This result can be though of some evidence of the fact that differences in monetary reward are not the same as the differences in real-term awards. This suggests that the differences in wages between regions compensate at least partly for differences in cost-of-living. In 1991, Blackaby and Murphy[9] estimated standardised geographical wage differentials[note 7] and then explained these geographical wage differentials with a set of weather,[note 8] environmental[note 9] and prices indexes.[note 10] The authors include other variables based on two other theories: efficiency wage and search theory. The results provide some evidence that workers are not suffering from money illusion as areas with prices higher by 10% than another area also have wages 10% higher. In consequence, wage do compensate for local differences in prices. In England, wages are usually thought of being better in the South than in the North of the country. Though Blackaby and Murphy[8] show that wages when controlled for individual characteristics, occupations characteristics, cost-of-living and industry mix are better in the North than in the South[note 11] for manual workers. Thus they conclude that it makes sense for unemployed in the North to wait and look for a job in the North as that is where they will get relatively better pay. This give some extra evidence that wage differentials compensate, at least partly, for geographical differences in cost-of-living.
Discussion
[edit]Possible confusion with other concepts
[edit]The terms compensation differential, pay differential, and wage differential (see wage dispersion or economic inequality) are also used in economics, but normally have a different meaning. They simply refer to differences in total pay (or the wage rate) in any context.[22] So a 'compensation differential' can be explained by many factors, such as differences in the skills of the workers in those jobs, the country or geographical area in which those jobs are performed, or the characteristics of the jobs themselves. A 'compensating differential', in contrast, refers exclusively to differences in pay due to differences in the jobs themselves, for a given worker (or for two identical workers).
In the theory of price indices, economists also use the term compensating variation, which is yet another unrelated concept. A 'compensating variation' is the change in wealth required to leave a consumer's well-being unchanged when prices change.
See also
[edit]References
[edit]- ^ Kaufman, Bruce E.; Hotchkiss, Julie L. (2005). "Education, Training, and Earnings Differentials: The Theory of Human Capital". The economics of labor markets (5th ed.). Harcourt College Publishers. ISBN 978-0-324-28879-7.
- ^ Jump up to: a b Rosen, Sherwin (1986). "The theory of equalizing differences". In Ashenfelter, Orley; Layard, Richard (eds.). The Handbook of Labor Economics. Vol. 1. New York: Elsevier. pp. 641–692. ISBN 978-0-444-87856-4.
- ^ Miller, Richard D. Jr. (2004). "Estimating the compensating differential for employer-provided health insurance". International Journal of Health Care Finance and Economics. 4 (1): 27–41. doi:10.1023/B:IHFE.0000019259.74756.65. PMID 15170963. S2CID 19313510.
- ^ Averett, Susan; Bodenhorn, Howard; Staisiunas, Justas (2003). "Unemployment risk and compensating differential in late-nineteenth century New Jersey manufacturing". National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper 9977. Cambridge, Massachusetts.
- ^ Biddle, Jeff E.; Zarkin, Gary A. (1988). "Worker preference and market compensation for job risk". Review of Economics and Statistics. 70 (4): 660–667. doi:10.2307/1935830. JSTOR 1935830.
- ^ Rao, Vijayendra; Gupta, Indrani; Lokshin, Michael; Jana, Smarajit (2003). "Sex workers and the cost of safe sex: the compensating differential for condom use among Calcutta prostitutes". Journal of Development Economics. 71 (2): 585–603. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.197.8491. doi:10.1016/S0304-3878(03)00025-7. S2CID 153608532.
- ^ Thaler, Richard; Rosen, Sherwin (1975). "The value of saving a life: evidence from the labor market". In Terleckyj, Nestor E. (ed.). Household production and consumption. New York: National Bureau of Economic Research. ISBN 978-0-87014-515-5.
- ^ Jump up to: a b Blackaby, D. H.; P. D. Murphy (1995). "Earnings, Unemployment and Britain's North-South Divide: Real or Imaginary?". Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics. 57 (4): 487–512. doi:10.1111/j.1468-0084.1995.tb00036.x.
- ^ Jump up to: a b Blackaby, D. H.; P. D. Murphy (1991). "Industry Characteristics and Inter-Regional Wage Differences". Scottish Journal of Political Economy. 38 (2): 142–161. doi:10.1111/j.1467-9485.1991.tb00307.x.
- ^ Jump up to: a b c García, Inmaculada; José Alberto Molina (March 2002). "Inter-regional wage differentials in Spain". Applied Economics Letters. 9 (4): 209–215. doi:10.1080/13504850110065849. ISSN 1350-4851. S2CID 154990389.
- ^ Jump up to: a b Shah, Anup; Walker, Martin (August 1983). "The distribution of regional earnings in the UK". Applied Economics. 15 (4): 507–520. doi:10.1080/00036848300000020. ISSN 0003-6846.
- ^ Smith, Adam (1776). An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of the Nations. London: W. Strahan and T. Cadell.
- ^ Smith, Robert (April 1979). "Compensating Wage Differentials and Public Policy: A Review". Industrial and Labor Relations Review. 32 (3): 339–352. doi:10.1177/001979397903200304. S2CID 153347601 – via JSTOR.
- ^ Morrisey, Michael (September–December 2001). "Why Do Employers Do What They Do? Compensating Differentials". International Journal of Health Care Finance and Economics. 1. No 3/4 (3–4): 195–201. doi:10.1023/A:1013776317034. PMID 14625925. S2CID 27712813 – via JSTOR.
- ^ Borjas, George (2016). Labor Economics. McGraw Hill Education. pp. 196–228. ISBN 978-0-07-802188-6.
- ^ Hwang, Mortensen, and Reed (October 1998). "Hedonic Wages and Labor Market Search". Journal of Labor Economics. 16 (4): 815–847. doi:10.1086/209907. S2CID 153533456 – via JSTOR.
{{cite journal}}
: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link) - ^ Jump up to: a b Oaxaca, Ronald (October 1973). "Male-Female Wage Differentials in Urban Labor Markets". International Economic Review. 14 (3): 693–709. doi:10.2307/2525981. JSTOR 2525981.
- ^ Jump up to: a b Reilly, Barry (1992). "An Analysis of Local Labour Market Wage Differentials". Regional Studies. 26 (3): 257–264. Bibcode:1992RegSt..26..257R. doi:10.1080/00343409212331346951. ISSN 0034-3404.
- ^ Pereira, João; Aurora Galego (2011). "Regional wage differentials in Portugal: Static and dynamic approaches". Papers in Regional Science. 90 (3): 529–548. Bibcode:2011PRegS..90..529P. doi:10.1111/j.1435-5957.2010.00328.x. hdl:10174/2738. ISSN 1435-5957.
- ^ Reward Regional Surveys Ltd (1981). Regional Surveys, Cost of Living Report, Regional Comparisons.
- ^ Jump up to: a b Johnston, Richard; Martin McKinney; Tom Stark (1996). "Regional Price Level Variations and Real Household Incomes in the United Kingdom, 1979/80–1993". Regional Studies. 30 (6): 567–578. Bibcode:1996RegSt..30..567J. doi:10.1080/00343409612331349868. ISSN 0034-3404.
- ^ Bender, Keith A. (1998). "The central government-private sector wage differential". Journal of Economic Surveys. 12 (2): 177–220. doi:10.1111/1467-6419.00052.
Notes
[edit]- ^ Aberdeen, Coventry, Kircaldy, Northampton, Rochdale and Swindon are the six local labour markets used.
- ^ They divided Spain into 5 main regions (North, South, East, Centre and Madrid) and used the Oaxaca technique
- ^ They use a cross sectional data for 1994 (European Community Household panel) combined with regional price and population data from the National Statistics Institute (INE). They have 4450 individual observations that were divided into 5 main regions (North, South, East, Centre and Madrid). They introduce controls into their wage equations for occupation, education, industry, gender, age, tenure and whether they have a second language.
- ^ They use data from the Quadros de Pessoal for 1995 and 2002. This data is compulsory for all employers with at least one employee. It is completed and sent to the ministry of employment of Portugal. It does not concern employees of public administration, the armed forces and self employed professionals. They considered only workers between 16 and 65 and excluded fisheries, agriculture and unpaid family workers and apprentices. They also excluded workers in Madeira and the Açores.
- ^ . Они корректируют свои регрессии по индивидуальным характеристикам, промышленности и стоимости жизни. Они ввели региональные чайники для 15 регионов: Большой Лондон, Юго -Восток, Уэст -Мидлендс, Северо -Запад, Шотландия (Западное побережье, восточное побережье, север и юг), Уэльс (юго -восток, а не на юго -восток), юго -запад, Восточный Мидлендс, восток, восток Англия, Йорк/Хамберсайд, Северо -Восток.
- ^ Описания в Шад и Уокер (1983) и в Johnston et al. (1996) не очень ясны. Хотя это так можно обобщить: группа вознаграждений предполагает, что домохозяйства с двумя взрослыми и двумя детьми в возрасте 10 и 13 лет являются представителями «общин». Из этих домохозяйств они собирают 200 розничных цен в 100 местах, в которые добавлены 18 региональных цен на страхование на топливо и автомобиль, а также 31 национальные цены, охватывающие газеты, марки, лицензии и т. Д., Цены взвешены в соответствии с восьми схемами расходов домохозяйств.
- ^ Авторы оценили уравнение заработной платы с полным набором промышленности, региональных манекенов и взаимодействия между ними, используя общее исследование домохозяйств 1982 года. Они ограничивали свою выборку лицам, которые работали более 27 часов и сообщали о еженедельных доходах, что привело к Выборка из 6999 человек. Они также контролировали индивидуальные характеристики (возраст, возраст, пол, опыт и образование).
- ^ Они использовали средние годовые дожди, солнечные дни, штор -дни… взятые из ежемесячного отчета о погоде метеорологических кабинетов.
- ^ Они использовали загрязнение атмосферы, дорожные заторы и общее обеспечение рекреационных объектов.
- ^ Они сопоставили свои данные с новыми данными обследования доходов того же года (1982). Они ввели дополнительный контроль за размер завода и усилия, основанные на работниках, оплаченных результатами. Они также включали данные о заработной плате союза. В Великобритании в 1982 году заработная плата, если она установлена коллективными переговорами, заключает национальную коллективную сделку, а также местные. Таким образом, они использовали пропорции людей, охватываемых любыми национальными переговорами, национальными и местными для каждой регионы своего анализа.
- ^ Юг определяется как юго-восток, юго-запад, Восточная Англия, Восточная Мидлендс.