Rent regulation
Part of a series on |
Living spaces |
---|
Rent regulation is a system of laws for the rental market of dwellings, with controversial effects on affordability of housing and tenancies. Generally, a system of rent regulation involves:
- Price controls, limits on the rent that a landlord may charge, typically called rent control or rent stabilization
- Eviction controls: codified standards by which a landlord may terminate a tenancy[1]: 1 [2]: 1
- Obligations on the landlord or tenant regarding adequate maintenance of the property
- A system of oversight and enforcement by an independent regulator and ombudsman
The loose term "rent control" covers a spectrum of regulation which can vary from setting the absolute amount of rent that can be charged, with no allowed increases, to placing different limits on the amount that rent can increase; these restrictions may continue between tenancies, or may be applied only within the duration of a tenancy.[3] As of 2016, at least 14 of the 36 OECD countries have some form of rent control in effect,[4] including four states in the United States.[5][6]
Rent regulation is implemented in many diverse forms. It is one of several classes of policies intended to improve housing affordability. Its efficacy and collateral impacts have been the subject of disagreement and controversy.[7] There is consensus among economists that rent control reduces the quality and quantity of housing units.[7]: 1 [8][9][10][11][12][13][14]
Forms of rent regulation
[edit]The loose term "rent control" can apply to several types of price control:
- "strict price ceilings", also known as rent freeze systems, or absolute or first generation rent controls, in which no increases in rent are allowed at all (rent is typically frozen at the rate existing when the law was enacted)
- "vacancy control", also known as strict or strong rent control, in which the rental price can rise, but continues to be regulated in between tenancies (a new tenant pays almost the same rent as the previous tenant) and
- "vacancy decontrol", also known as tenancy or second-generation rent control, which limits price increases during a tenancy, but allows rents to rise to market rate between tenancies (new tenants pay market rate rent, but increases are limited as long as they remain).[15]
Effectiveness
[edit]Rent price controls remain the most controversial element of a system of rent regulation. Modern rent controls (sometimes called rent leveling or rent stabilization) are intended to protect tenants in privately owned residential properties from excessive rent increases. This is usually done by mandating gradual rent increases or rent freezes, while at the same time ensuring that landlords receive a return on their investment that is deemed fair by the controlling authority.[citation needed]
There is consensus among economists that rent control reduces the quality and quantity of rental housing units.[7]: 1 [8][9][10][11][13][14][16][17] However, some economists challenge this consensus and argue that controls do not have a statistically significant impact on quantity and quality of housing units.[18][19][20][21]
A number of neo-classical and Keynesian economists say that some forms of rent control regulations create shortages and exacerbate scarcity in the housing market by discouraging private investment in the rental market. In addition, there would be a dead weight loss and inefficiency since some of the loss due to price ceilings is never gained again.[22][23] This analysis targeted nominal rent freezes, and the studies conducted were mainly focused on rental prices in Manhattan, or elsewhere in the United States.[citation needed]
In a 1992 stratified, random survey of 464 US economists, economics graduate students, and members of the American Economic Association, 93% "generally agreed" or "agreed with provisos" that "A ceiling on rents reduces the quantity and quality of housing available."[24]: 204 [25]: 1
A 2009 review of the economic literature[23]: 106 by Blair Jenkins through EconLit covering theoretical and empirical research on multiple aspects of the issue, including housing availability, maintenance and housing quality, rental rates, political and administrative costs, and redistribution, for both first generation and second generation rent control systems, found that "the economics profession has reached a rare consensus: Rent control creates many more problems than it solves".[23]: 105 [26]: 1 [27]: 1 [28]: 1 .
In a 2012 poll of 41 economists by the Initiative on Global Markets (IGM) Economic Experts Panel, which queried opinions on the statement "Local ordinances that limit rent increases for some rental housing units, such as in New York and San Francisco, have had a positive impact over the past three decades on the amount and quality of broadly affordable rental housing in cities that have used them," 13 members said they strongly disagreed, 20 disagreed, 1 agreed, and 7 either did not answer, were undecided, or had no opinion.[29] [2]: 1 [30]: 1 .
A 2021 Columbia Business School study found that there are benefits to rent regulation,[31] arguing that "the housing stability they provide disproportionately benefits low-income households. These insurance benefits trade off against the aggregate and spatial distortions in housing and labor markets that accompany such policies."
In David Sims's 2007 study of the deregulation of the housing market in Cambridge, Massachusetts, he found that "rent control had little effect on the construction of new housing but did encourage owners to shift units away from rental status and reduced rents substantially."[32]
In a 2013 analysis of the body of economic research on rent control by Peter Tatian at the Urban Institute, he stated that "The conclusion seems to be that rent stabilization doesn't do a good job of protecting its intended beneficiaries—poor or vulnerable renters—because the targeting of the benefits is very haphazard.", and concluded that: "Given the current research, there seems to be little one can say in favor of rent control." [26]: 1 [2]: 1 [33]: 1
Many economists suggest housing subsidies as a way to make housing more affordable to renters without distorting the housing market as much as rent control, but expanding the existing subsidy programs would require sharp increases in government spending.[7]
Paul Krugman writes that rent control inhibits construction of new housing, creates bitter tenant–landlord relations, and in markets with not all apartments under rent control, causes an increase in rents for uncontrolled units.[25]
Thomas Sowell writes that rent control reduces the supply of housing,[34]: 4 and has stated that rent control increases urban blight.[34]: 5 [35]: 1
The Swedish economist Assar Lindbeck, a housing expert, said that "rent control appears to be the most efficient technique presently known to destroy a city – except for bombing".[36][37]
A study by NYU's Furman Center takes a more positive view on rent regulation, especially as a tool to slow gentrification: "Although rent regulation is ill-targeted if viewed as a purely redistributional program," write the three authors of the study, "as a program to promote longer-term lower rent tenancies for the tenants who benefit from it, even in hot rental markets, it seems to succeed."[38]
California studies
[edit]In 1994, San Francisco voters passed a ballot initiative which expanded the city's existing rent control laws to include small multi-unit apartments with four or fewer units, built prior to 1980 (about 30% of the city's rental housing stock at the time).[39]: 7 [40]: 1 [41]: 1 A 2019 study found that San Francisco's rent control laws reduced tenant displacement from rent controlled units in the short-term, but resulted in landlords removing 30% of the rent controlled units from the rental market (by conversion to condos or TICs) which led to a 15% citywide decrease in total rental units, and a 7% increase in citywide rents.[42][40][41][43][44]: 1 [45]: 1 [46]
History
[edit]This section needs expansion. You can help by adding to it. (March 2019) |
Early modern Europe
[edit]Rent control was used in Rome as early as 1470 to protect Jewish residents from price gouging. Since Jews in the Papal States were forbidden to own property, they were dependent on Christian landlords, who charged them high rents. In 1562, Pope Pius IV granted Jews the right to own property worth up to 1,500 Roman scudi and enacted rent stabilization. In 1586, Pope Sixtus V issued a bull ordering landlords to rent out houses to Jewish tenants at reasonable rates.[47]
Politics
[edit]This section needs expansion. You can help by adding to it. (March 2019) |
Rent regulation by country
[edit]Australia
[edit]Rental regulations are administered by the state and territory governments. Rent control and freezes were features of the First and Second World War, the Great Depression, and the early stages of the COVID-19 pandemic.[48]
Australian Capital Territory
[edit]The Australian Capital Territory (ACT) is currently the only jurisdiction with regulation specifying maximum rent increases. Rents can only be increased for sitting tenants once a year by a maximum of 110% of the consumer price index for the cost of rent in the ACT.[49][50][51] Rents between tenancies are not regulated, and are allowed to rise to market rate upon vacancy (vacancy decontrol).[50][52] Rent increases above the amount prescribed by regulation may be disputed by application to the ACT Civil and Administrative Tribunal (ACAT).[53][54] Other Australian jurisdictions allow for rent increases every six to twelve months with variable notice periods.[55]
New South Wales
[edit]New South Wales has a small number of tenants who are not covered by the Residential Tenancies Act 2010 (NSW),[56] but rather continuing provisions of the repealed Landlord and Tenant (Amendment) Act 1948 (NSW).[57][58][59][60] Such ‘protected tenants’ pay a regulated ‘fair rent’ set either through a Section 17A agreement registered with NSW Fair Trading, or a magistrate sitting as the Fair Rents Board (NSW).[58][61]
Canada
[edit]In Canada, there are rent regulation laws in each province. For example, in Ontario the Residential Tenancies Act 2006 requires that prices for rented properties do not rise more than 2.5 percent each year, or a lower figure fixed by a government minister.
China
[edit]China announced in August 2021 new nationwide rent regulations that cap maximum yearly rent increases to 5% in all urban areas, which comprise over 2/3 of the population and include most of the ~250 million renters in the country.[62]
France
[edit]Rent regulations are determined in France based on the Rent Reference Index, which serves as the basis for what landlords can increase yearly rents by.[63] In July 2022, France introduced a new cap on yearly rent increase of a maximum of 3.5% for one year.[64]
Germany
[edit]German rent regulation is found in the "Civil Code" (the Bürgerliches Gesetzbuch) in § 535 to § 580a.[65] As common in German law, regulations are structured into an abstract, more general part that applies to all contracts of a certain type, followed by a more specific section for individual fields of application of this type of contract. Specific regulations for rental contracts governing apartments range from §§ 549 - 577a BGB.
The German law differentiates between the rental price at the starting point of the contract and rent increases throughout the duration of the contract. Generally, the rental price at the starting point of the contract is determined by the contractual agreement between the parties. Only in designated regions with a strained housing market, the rental price at the beginning of the rental agreement are capped by law. Increases in the rental prices throughout the duration of a rental contract are required to follow a "rent level" (Mietspiegel), which is a database of local reference rent prices. This collects all rent prices of new rental contracts of the past four years, and landlords may only increase prices on their property in line with rents in the same locality. Usury Rents are prohibited altogether, so that any price rises above 20 per cent over three years are unlawful.[66]
Tenants may be evicted against their will through a court procedure for a good reason, and in the normal case only with a minimum of three months' notice.[67] Tenants receive unlimited duration of their rental agreement unless the duration is explicitly halted. In practice, landlords have little incentive to change tenants as rental price increases beyond inflation are constrained. During the period of the tenancy, a person's tenancy may only be terminated for very good reasons. A system of rights for the rental property to be maintained by the landlord is designed to ensure quality of housing. Many states, such as Berlin, have a constitutional right to adequate housing, and require buildings to make dwelling spaces of a certain size and ceiling height.[citation needed]
In 2020, Berlin implemented a rent freeze, which was unprecedented in the German housing market. It benefitted sitting renters, but it substantially reduced the supply of new housing, harming those looking for a dwelling. The rent freeze was repealed in 2021.[68]
Netherlands
[edit]Yearly rent increases in the Netherlands are capped at a maximum of inflation + 1%, calculated as 3.3% in 2022.[69]
Spain
[edit]The Catalonia region of Spain passed a rent-regulation law in September 2020.[70]
United Kingdom
[edit]Rent regulation covered the whole of the UK private sector rental market from 1915 to 1980. However, from the Housing Act 1980, it became Conservative Party policy to deregulate and dismantle rent regulation. Regulation for all new tenancies was abolished by the Housing Act 1988, leaving the basic regulatory framework was "freedom of contract" by the landlord to set any price. Rent regulations survive among a small number of council houses, and often the rates set by local authorities mirror escalating prices in the non-regulated private market.
United States
[edit]Rent regulation in the United States is an issue for each state. In 1921, the US Supreme Court case of Block v. Hirsh[71] held by a majority that regulation of rents in the District of Columbia as a temporary emergency measure was constitutional, but shortly afterward in 1924 in Chastleton Corp v. Sinclair[72] the same law was unanimously struck down by the Supreme Court. After the 1930s New Deal, the Supreme Court ceased to interfere with social and economic legislation, and many states adopted rules.[citation needed] In the 1986 case of Fisher v. City of Berkeley,[73] the US Supreme court held that there was no incompatibility between rent control and the Sherman Act.
Rent control existed in several Massachusetts communities from 1970 to 1994. During this time, at least 20% of all rent-controlled apartments in Cambridge housed the rich.[74] The vast majority housed middle- and high-income earners.[74] They included Frederik, Crown Prince of Denmark.[74]
As of 2018, 4 states (California, New York, New Jersey, and Maryland) and the District of Columbia have localities in which some form of residential rent control is in effect (for normal structures, excluding mobile homes).[5][6] 37 states either prohibit or preempt rent control, while 9 states allow their cities to enact rent control, but have no cities that have implemented it.[5][6] For the localities with rent control, it often covers a large percentage of that city's stock of rental units: For example, in some of the largest markets: in New York City in 2011, 45% of rental units were either "rent-stabilized" or "rent-controlled", (these are different legal classifications in NYC)[75]: 1 in the District of Columbia in 2014, just over 50% of rental units were rent-controlled, [76]: 1 in San Francisco, as of 2014, about 75% of all rental units were rent-controlled, [77]: 1 and in Los Angeles in 2014, 80% of multifamily units were rent controlled.[78]: 1
In 2019 California passed a statewide rent cap for the next 10 years which limits yearly rent increases to 5% plus regional inflation.[79]
In 2019 Oregon's legislature passed a bill which made the state the first in the nation to adopt a state-wide rent control policy. This new law limits annual rent increases to inflation plus 7 percent, includes vacancy decontrol (market rate between tenancies), exempts new construction for 15 years, and keeps the current state ban on local rent control policies (state level preemption) intact.[80]: 1 [81]: 1
In November 2021, voters in Saint Paul, Minnesota passed a rent control ballot initiative which capped annual rent increases at 3 percent, included vacancy control, and did not exempt new construction, nor allow inflation to be added to the allowable rate increase.[82][83] This was followed by an 80% reduction in requests for new multifamily housing permits, while in neighboring Minneapolis, where voters authorized the city council to craft a rent control ordinance, yet to be enacted—which may exempt new construction from the rent control caps—permits were up 68%.[82][84]
See also
[edit]References
[edit]- ^ Branco, Marc (20 February 2011). "Rent and Eviction Control Laws". marcbrancolaw.com. Archived from the original on 31 March 2012. Retrieved 19 August 2018.
- ^ Jump up to: a b c Pender, Kathleen (10 September 2016). "Rent control spreading to Bay Area suburbs, to economists' dismay". The San Francisco Chronicle. Archived from the original on 8 October 2016. Retrieved 18 August 2018.
- ^ See the section on Rent regulation#Forms of rent regulation for more detail.
- ^ "PH6.1 RENTAL REGULATION" (PDF). OECD.org - Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development. 21 December 2016. Archived (PDF) from the original on 16 February 2017. Retrieved 26 November 2018.
- ^ Jump up to: a b c "RENT CONTROL BY STATE LAW" (PDF). National Multifamily Housing Council. 3 September 2020. Archived (PDF) from the original on 4 September 2020. Retrieved 4 September 2020.
- ^ Jump up to: a b c "Residential Rent Control Law Guide By State". LandLord.com. Archived from the original on 13 June 2018. Retrieved 3 August 2018.
- ^ Jump up to: a b c d Dougherty, Conor (12 October 2018). "Why Rent Control Is a Lightning Rod". The New York Times. Retrieved 26 March 2019.
- ^ Jump up to: a b Baumol, William J; Blinder, Alan S. (1994). Economics Principles and Policy (6th ed.). Dryden Press. pp. 92–93, 379. ISBN 0-03-098927-2.
- ^ Jump up to: a b Cooter, Robert; Ulen, Thomas (1997). Law and Economics 2nd Edition. Addison-Wesley. pp. 32–33.
- ^ Jump up to: a b David A Besanko; Ronald R. Braeutigam (2008). "10.5". Microeconomics (3rd ed.). Hoboken, New Jersey: John Wiley & Sons. pp. 374–377. ISBN 978-0470-04924-2.
- ^ Jump up to: a b B. Douglas Bernheim; Michael D Whinston (2008). Microeconomics (1st ed.). McGraw-Hill Irwin. p. 565. ISBN 978-0-07-290027-9.
- ^ See also the "Effectiveness" section for more references supporting this statement.
- ^ Jump up to: a b Mankiw, N. Gregory (2015). Principles of Economics. Boston, MA: Cengage Learning. p. 31. ISBN 978-1-305-58512-6.
Propositions about Which Most Economists Agree: ... A ceiling on rents reduces the quantity and quality of housing available
- ^ Jump up to: a b Brandts, Jordi; Busom, Isabel; Lopez-Mayan, Cristina; Panadés, Judith (2022). "Pictures are worth many words: Effectiveness of visual communication in dispelling the rent-control misconception". SSRN Electronic Journal. doi:10.2139/ssrn.4037381. hdl:2445/183641. ISSN 1556-5068.
We focus on the popular belief that rent control allows more families to find affordable housing. The support for this policy is very large and widespread among the public in many countries. This belief, however, is at odds with scientific consensus arising from economic research. In a poll to economists from the IGM Economic Experts Panel, 95% strongly disagree that rent capping will increase the quantity of affordable housing.
- ^ Cruz, Christian (19 January 2009). "The pros and cons of rent control". Global Property Guide. Archived from the original on 27 February 2010. Retrieved 5 August 2018.
- ^ https://housingevidence.ac.uk/wp-content/uploads/2022/11/CPG-rent-control-final-011122.pdf
- ^ Marsh, Alex; Gibb, Kenneth; Soaita, Adriana Mihaela (1 August 2022). "Rent regulation: unpacking the debates". International Journal of Housing Policy. 23 (4): 734–757. doi:10.1080/19491247.2022.2089079. hdl:1983/e12d8c29-a7c0-4cea-ba0e-85363841d111. ISSN 1949-1247.
- ^ Marsh, Alex; Gibb, Kenneth; Soaita, Adriana Mihaela (1 August 2022). "Rent regulation: unpacking the debates". International Journal of Housing Policy. 23 (4): 734–757. doi:10.1080/19491247.2022.2089079. hdl:1983/e12d8c29-a7c0-4cea-ba0e-85363841d111. ISSN 1949-1247.
- ^ Gilderbloom, John I.; Ye, Lin (2007). "Thirty Years of Rent Control: A Survey of New Jersey Cities". Journal of Urban Affairs. 29 (2): 207–220. doi:10.1111/j.1467-9906.2007.00334.x. S2CID 153505704.
- ^ Ambrosius, Joshua D.; Gilderbloom, John I.; Steele, William J.; Meares, Wesley L.; Keating, Dennis (2015). "Forty years of rent control: Reexamining New Jersey's moderate local policies after the great recession". Cities. 49: 121–133. doi:10.1016/j.cities.2015.08.001.
- ^ "Why Rent Control Works".
- ^ C Rapkin,The Private Rental Housing Market in New York City (1966) and G Sternlieb, The Urban Housing Dilemma (1972)
- ^ Jump up to: a b c Jenkins, Blair (1 January 2009). "Rent Control: Do Economists Agree?" (PDF). American Institute for Economic Research. Archived (PDF) from the original on 29 September 2017. Retrieved 14 August 2018.
- ^ Alston, Richard M.; Kearl, J. R.; Vaughan, Michael B. (1 May 1992). "Is There a Consensus Among Economists in the 1990s?" (PDF). The American Economic Review. 82 (2): 203–209. JSTOR 2117401. Archived (PDF) from the original on 1 September 2006.
- ^ Jump up to: a b Krugman, Paul (7 June 2000). "Reckonings; A Rent Affair". The New York Times. Archived from the original on 6 April 2009. Retrieved 10 August 2018.
- ^ Jump up to: a b Tatian, Peter (2 January 2013). "Is Rent Control Good Policy?". Urban Institute. Archived from the original on 3 July 2015. Retrieved 19 August 2018.
- ^ Beyer, Scott (24 April 2015). "How Ironic: America's Rent-Controlled Cities Are Its Least Affordable". Forbes. Archived from the original on 19 July 2015. Retrieved 11 September 2018.
- ^ Valdez, Roger (18 December 2017). "Rent Control Doesn't Help Renters: Some In Washington State Want To Try It Anyway". Forbes. Archived from the original on 23 December 2017. Retrieved 13 September 2018.
- ^ "Rent Control". Initiative on Global Markets. 7 February 2012. Archived from the original on 11 December 2016. Retrieved 14 August 2018.
- ^ Matthews, Dylan (20 August 2013). "Which economist do you agree with most? Take this quiz to find out!". The Washington Post. Archived from the original on 16 August 2018. Retrieved 15 August 2018.
- ^ Favilukis, Jack Y.; Mabille, Pierre; Van Nieuwerburgh, Stijn (11 June 2021). "Affordable Housing and City Welfare". Columbia Business School Research Paper Series. Rochester, NY. SSRN 3265918.
- ^ Sims, David P. (1 January 2007). "Out of control: What can we learn from the end of Massachusetts rent control?". Journal of Urban Economics. 61 (1): 129–151. doi:10.1016/j.jue.2006.06.004. ISSN 0094-1190.
- ^ Jaffe, Eric (9 April 2013). "Some People Will Do Crazy Things for a Rent-Controlled Apartment in NYC". CityLab - The Atlantic. Archived from the original on 12 September 2018. Retrieved 11 September 2018.
- ^ Jump up to: a b Sowell, Thomas. 2008. Economic Facts and Fallacies. Basic Books, ISBN 0-465-00349-4.
- ^ Sawhill, Ray (10 November 1999). "Black and right - Thomas Sowell talks about the arrogance of liberal elites and the loneliness of the black conservative". Salon. Archived from the original on 7 December 2011. Retrieved 22 September 2018.
- ^ Fraser Nelson (2 May 2014). "Low-rent Labour is positioning itself as the Ukip of the Left". The Daily Telegraph. Retrieved 29 October 2016.
- ^ Rosalsky, Greg (5 March 2019). "The Return of Rent Control". NPR.
- ^ Herrine, Luke; Yager, Jessica; Mian, Nadia (26 October 2016). "Gentrification Response: A Survey of Strategies to Maintain Neighborhood Economic Diversity" (PDF). The Furman Center. Retrieved 2 January 2022.
- ^ Diamond, Rebecca; McQuade, Tim; Qian, Franklin (11 October 2017). "The Effects of Rent Control Expansion on Tenants, Landlords, and Inequality: Evidence from San Francisco" (PDF). National Bureau of Economic Research. Archived (PDF) from the original on 3 August 2018. Retrieved 7 August 2018.
- ^ Jump up to: a b Murphy, Katy (2 November 2017). "Rent-control policy 'likely fueled the gentrification of San Francisco,' study finds - As California debates rent caps, economists offer a cautionary note". The San Jose Mercury News. Archived from the original on 4 January 2018. Retrieved 7 August 2018.
- ^ Jump up to: a b Truong, Kevin (9 November 2017). "Rent control linked to gentrification in San Francisco, Stanford study says". American City Business Journals. Archived from the original on 2 December 2018. Retrieved 1 December 2018.
- ^ Qian, Franklin; McQuade, Tim; Diamond, Rebecca (2019). "The Effects of Rent Control Expansion on Tenants, Landlords, and Inequality: Evidence from San Francisco". American Economic Review. 109 (9): 3365–3394. doi:10.1257/aer.20181289. ISSN 0002-8282.
- ^ Robertson, Michelle (3 November 2017). "Rent-control policies likely 'fueled' SF gentrification, Stanford economists say". San Francisco Chronicle. Archived from the original on 3 December 2017. Retrieved 7 August 2018.
- ^ Delgadillo, Natalie (14 February 2018). "Does Rent Control Do More Harm Than Good? - A new study suggests that policies meant to keep rents down actually jack them up overall, reduce the rental stock and fuel gentrification". Governing. Archived from the original on 22 February 2018. Retrieved 7 August 2018.
- ^ Misra, Tanvi (29 January 2018). "Rent Control: a Reckoning". CityLab. Archived from the original on 1 February 2018. Retrieved 30 November 2018.
- ^ Andrews, Edmund (2 February 2018). "Rent Control's Winners and Losers - With rents going through the roof in hot cities, the hunt is on for a better way to protect tenants from being priced out of their homes". Stanford Graduate School of Business. Archived from the original on 9 March 2018. Retrieved 11 December 2018.
- ^ Willis, John W. (1950). "Short History of Rent Control Laws". Cornell Law Review. 36 (1): 54–94. Retrieved 7 March 2019 – via Cornell University Law Library.
- ^ z5076905 (29 August 2022). "Is it time to talk about rent control in Australia?". UNSW Newsroom. Retrieved 4 November 2022.
{{cite web}}
: CS1 maint: numeric names: authors list (link) - ^ ACT Government (1 April 2023). "Part 5, Residential Tenancies Act 1997 (ACT)". ACT Legislation Register. Retrieved 25 June 2023.
- ^ Jump up to: a b ACT Government (1 April 2023). "Part 2, Residential Tenancies Regulation 1998 (ACT)". ACT Legislation Register. Retrieved 25 June 2023.
- ^ ACT Government Justice and Community Safety Directorate (March 2021). "The Renting Book" (PDF). The Renting Book. pp. 28–31. Archived (PDF) from the original on 25 October 2022. Retrieved 4 November 2022.
- ^ Clun, Rachel (25 June 2023). "The one place in Australia with rent control". The Sydney Morning Herald. Retrieved 25 June 2023.
- ^ Legal Aid ACT (25 June 2023). "Tenancy: Rent Increases" (PDF). Legal Aid ACT. Retrieved 25 June 2023.
- ^ ACT Civil and Administrative Tribunal (ACAT) (25 June 2023). "About ACAT". ACT Civil and Administrative Tribunal. Retrieved 25 June 2023.
- ^ "How Much Is Rent Allowed to Increase (And How Often)?". Property Update. 24 October 2022. Retrieved 4 November 2022.
- ^ NSW Legislation (13 January 2023). "Residential Tenancies Act 2010 (NSW)". NSW Legislation. Retrieved 25 June 2023.
- ^ NSW Legislation. "Landlord and Tenant (Amendment) Act 1948 (NSW)". NSW Legislation. Retrieved 25 June 2023.
- ^ Jump up to: a b Tenants' Union of NSW (25 June 2023). "Protected Tenants Infosheet". Tenants' Union of NSW. Retrieved 25 June 2023.
- ^ McKenny, Leesha (22 November 2012). "Protected tenants face uncertain future". The Sydney Morning Herald. Retrieved 25 June 2023.
- ^ Schneller, Edwina (March 2013). "Protected tenancies: history and proposals for reform" (PDF). NSW Parliamentary Research Service. Retrieved 25 June 2023.
- ^ Older Persons' Tenants Service (June 2014). "2014 CPSA Guide to Protected Tenancies in NSW" (PDF). Tenants' Union of NSW. Retrieved 25 June 2023.
- ^ "China to put a cap on urban rents to improve housing affordability". South China Morning Post. 31 August 2021. Retrieved 26 July 2022.
- ^ "Indice de référence des loyers (IRL)". www.service-public.fr (in French). Retrieved 27 July 2022.
- ^ "France to limit rent rises to help households with cost of living". The Local France. 8 July 2022. Retrieved 27 July 2022.
- ^ English translation available: §§ 535 ff. BGB
- ^ M Haffner, M Elsinga and J Hoekstra (2008). "Rent Regulation: The Balance between Private Landlords and Tenants in Six European Countries". International Journal of Housing Policy. 8 (2): 217–233. doi:10.1080/14616710802037466. S2CID 154288124.
- ^ BGB §573c
- ^ Sagner, Pekka; Voigtländer, Michael (2022). "Supply side effects of the Berlin rent freeze". International Journal of Housing Policy. 23 (4): 692–711. doi:10.1080/19491247.2022.2059844. ISSN 1949-1247. S2CID 248615020.
- ^ Koninkrijksrelaties, Ministerie van Binnenlandse Zaken en (14 May 2013). "Rented housing - Housing - Government.nl". www.government.nl. Retrieved 27 July 2022.
- ^ Marc González (10 September 2020). "Catalonia now has a rent control law, via the votes of JxCat, ERC, CUP and Comuns". ElNacional.cat. Retrieved 27 October 2020.
- ^ 256 U.S. 135 (1921)
- ^ 264 U.S. 543 (1924)
- ^ 475 U.S. 260 (1986)
- ^ Jump up to: a b c "Renters who needed to move couldn't qualify". Mass Landlords, Inc. Retrieved 3 January 2024.
- ^ Pereira, Ivan (11 January 2015). "Battle looms over NYC rent stabilization law". Newsday. Archived from the original on 21 February 2015. Retrieved 4 December 2018.
- ^ Weiner, Aaron (12 December 2014). "Losing Control - D.C.'s rent control laws are supposed to keep housing affordable. So how do landlords keep getting around them?". Washington City Paper. Archived from the original on 26 May 2016. Retrieved 4 December 2018.
- ^ Cutler, Kim-Mai (14 April 2014). "How Burrowing Owls Lead To Vomiting Anarchists (Or SF's Housing Crisis Explained)". TechCrunch. Archived from the original on 30 April 2014. Retrieved 4 December 2018.
- ^ Bergman, Ben (12 September 2014). "LA Rent: Has rent control been successful in Los Angeles?". Southern California Public Radio. Archived from the original on 13 September 2014. Retrieved 4 December 2018.
- ^ Dillon, Liam (8 October 2019). "California will limit rent increases under bill signed by Gov. Gavin Newsom". Los Angeles Times.
- ^ Ingber, Sasha (27 February 2019). "Oregon Set To Pass The First Statewide Rent Control Bill". NPR.org. Archived from the original on 6 March 2019. Retrieved 6 March 2019.
- ^ Njus, Elliot (28 February 2019). "Oregon Gov. Kate Brown signs nation's first statewide rent control law". OregonLive. Archived from the original on 5 March 2019. Retrieved 6 March 2019.
- ^ Jump up to: a b Britschgi, Christian (22 March 2022). "America's Most Controversial Rent Control Law Is Getting a Hasty Makeover - A collapse in new development activity followed St. Paul voters' approval of a strict, vaguely written rent control ordinance. City and state officials are scrambling over how best to fix the new law". Reason.
Tomorrow the St. Paul City Council will discuss the details of implementing Question 1, a brief, voter-passed ordinance that caps annual rent increases at 3 percent and which includes none of the typical exemptions or allowances for new construction, vacant units, or inflation. ... California and Oregon policies also include a number of other exemptions to their state-level rent control laws. They allow property owners, up to a point, to add inflation to allowable rent increases. They both allow landlords to raise rents as high as they want between tenants and have higher caps on rent increases: 5 percent in California and 7 percent in Oregon.
- ^ Galioto, Katie (20 November 2021). "Fearing a spike, tenant advocates keep a close eye on St. Paul rents". Star Tribune.
More than 30,000 St. Paul residents — about 53% of voters — approved an ordinance by referendum earlier this month that will cap annual rent increases at 3%. The city has yet to hammer out the finer points of its new policy, which has been pegged as one of the most stringent rent control measures in the nation because it does not allow landlords to raise rents once a tenant moves out, does not exempt new construction and is not tied to inflation.
- ^ Callaghan, Peter (16 March 2022). "Minnesota Senate committee moves bill to retroactively cancel rent control measures passed by voters in Minneapolis, St. Paul". MinnPost.
Draheim also cited Census Bureau statistics that show requests for housing permits has fallen 80 percent in St. Paul since the passage of the referendum. In Minneapolis, which hasn't drafted an ordinance yet and where new buildings could be exempt from caps, permits are up 68 percent.
Дальнейшее чтение
[ редактировать ]- Р. Арнотт, «Время ревизионизма в сфере контроля за арендной платой?» (1995) 9 (1) Журнал экономических перспектив 99
- А. Анас, «Контроль за арендной платой в странах с соответствующей экономикой: модель регулирования европейского рынка жилья» (1997) 15 (1) Журнал финансов и экономики недвижимости 111–37
- Т. Эллингсен и П. Энглунд, «Регулирование арендной платы: введение» (2003) 10 Обзор экономической политики Швеции 3
- Х. Линд, «Регулирование арендной платы: концептуальный и сравнительный анализ» (2001) 1(1) Международный журнал жилищной политики 41
- К. Рэпкин, Рынок частного арендного жилья в Нью-Йорке (1966)
- Г. Штернлиб, Дилемма городского жилья (1972)
- П. Вайцман, «Экономика и регулирование арендной платы: призыв к новой перспективе» (1984–1985) 13 Обзор правовых и социальных изменений Нью-Йоркского университета 975–988.
- М. Хаффнер, М. Элсинга и Дж. Хукстра, «Регулирование арендной платы: баланс между частными арендодателями и арендаторами в шести европейских странах» (2008 г.) 8 (2) Международный журнал жилищной политики 217
- Холодилин, Константин А. (2024). « Эффекты контроля за арендной платой через призму эмпирических исследований: почти полный обзор литературы ». Журнал жилищной экономики . 63